6: Incentives in Natural law societies

Written by Annie Nymous on . Posted in 1: Possible Societies, 2: Part Two: Natural Law Societies, Books

When we arrived in the ancient past, the land was already healthy.  Nature created a balanced ecosystem. This is the entire reason we get our checks each year:  We are getting a part of the benefits of a healthy ecosystem.  Since it is healthy, it produces an immense bounty each year.

We share the bounty by sharing the basic productivity of the land, the $2.4 million that represents the money value of the bounty. 

The land is producing a flow of free cash.  This truly is free:  we don’t have to do anything to get it.  But there are things we can do to cause us to stop getting it.  If we harm the land, it won’t produce as much.  We will still have to pay costs.  But there won’t be as much left over.  This is the money the human race shares.  The less we have to share, the less we each get.

If any harm comes to the land, we all suffer. 

We don’t just suffer the way people in territorial sovereignty societies do, by feeling sad that their children’s legacy has been stolen or having to put up with the mental agony of seeing a devastated ecosystem.  We suffer in a real way that we can all measure.  If harm comes to the land, our incomes fall.

Some of us have incomes from other activities and don’t care much.  Tanya sells eggs, Dennis runs the bar, and many other people have businesses that generate money.  To these people, the $2,000 they get from their share of the bounty of the Pastland Farm may not be very important.  You may be one of these people:  it may not matter much to you. 

But if you don’t care, you better not let other people around you know it is not a priority.  This is one thing we all share. We are all in the same boat. Destruction doesn’t just hurt you financially, it hurts everyone financially.  Anyone who does any harm to the land, or lets harm come to it (by standing by and not interference in things that may harm it) is stealing from every single member of the human race. 

If you talk casually about something you did that harmed the land, or something you let happen that harmed the land, you can expect extreme levels of anger from everyone around you.  It is not a minor thing.  We may have disagreements about a lot of different things.  But there is one thing that we will all agree on:  harm to the world hurts every single person on earth.

Some, of course, are hurt more than others.  Some people have no outside income.  Their only income is their share of the bounty of the world.  Two thousand dollars a year is not a lot of money to live on.  These people don’t eat steak and lobster at fancy restaurants with live bands.  They have boiled rice, perhaps a single egg per day, and meat once or twice a week.  A few dollars a year less and the meat has to cut back; a little more and they don’t get eggs.  If you don’t think keeping the environmental healthy is important, you better not let them know you feel this way.  If you are talking to anyone you will be careful about the topic. Even saying something that implies you might not care as much as the others do can turn people against you.

Other Natural Law Societies

Our people in Pastland didn’t create a natural law society intentionally. 

When we passed the moratorium, we weren’t trying to ‘create a society.’

We just saw that certain topics led to conflicts which often got violent; people could get hurt or killed.  Our people were all raised in societies that teach children that they are supposed to love their country, be willing to kill for it if asked, and be willing to accept death, if this is the only way to protect the country.  They are taught that violence is not only permissible, it is required if people won’t respect the sovereign rights of their country.  When people decided the land around them was the sovereign territory of their country, and saw that other people weren’t going to respect their rights, this training kicked in. They were supposed to get violent. It was the right thing to do.

We saw that the arguments over which country the land was in led to conflicts that often got violent.  These arguments could break out and get violent at any time.  We didn’t want to have to deal with these arguments and worry about all the other matters related to being cast millions of years in time. We didn’t want to make any permanent and absolute decisions.  The idea of nations owning land was not off the table entirely.  We just didn’t want to have to deal with this issue immediately. We wanted to have time to solve other problems.  Then, if people really thought we needed countries and wanted to form them, we could discuss this.  The moratorium was just a temporary pause in these matters.  Unintentionally, we created the same basic rule that was the prime directive of thousands of different societies that existed for tens of thousands of years in the Americas, before the conquest of these societies began in 1493.

We didn’t create the environmental intentionally either.  We didn’t sit down and decide we wanted everyone to be on guard against harm to our world.  The incentives to protect the environment were just side effects of flows of value that naturally take place in natural law societies.  The land around us is unowned so the bounty it produces is not owned.  We divide it by dividing the $2.4 million in basic productivity left on the table toward the end of every yearly meeting.  If there is less to divide, everyone suffers.  If there is more to divide, everyone benefits.  Any society that is built on this foundation will have the same incentives.

A great many different natural law societies existed in the Americas before the conquest. Some had enormous cities, used money for transactions, had extensive markets and many goods and services available, just as we have in Pastland.  Other groups lived simply and roamed the hunting wild game, trading meat and livestock products for other goods at pow-wows or other gatherings, and rarely even seeing money.  But they all shared a common feature: no human entity owned any part of the planet around them.  They all lived on a very bountiful world and shared the bounty.  If they could keep the land healthy, it would remain bountiful. If the land was harmed, they had less to share and everyone got less.

Quotes about the People of The Land Beyond The Western Ocean

When Columbus arrived in the Caribbean in October of 1492, very large numbers of people rowed out in canoes to meet him.  He had arrived in an area with thousands of islands, each with large populations.  They made different things and had different things to trade, either with people from other islands in the Caribbean, or from people from anywhere that might have something they wanted to exchange for things they had. 

Columbus visited many of these islands.  He was totally amazed by the incredible health of the land.  He had never seen anything like it.  Here are his words describing several different islands sequentially:

 

‘This is a large and level island, with trees extremely flourishing, and streams of water; there is a large lake in the middle of the island, but no mountains: the whole is completely covered with verdure and delightful to behold.  The natives are an inoffensive people, and so desirous to possess any thing they saw with us, that they kept swimming off to the ships with whatever they could find, and readily bartered for any article we saw fit to give them in return, even such as broken platters and fragments of glass.

Near the islet I have mentioned were groves of trees, the most beautiful I have ever seen, with their foliage as verdant as we see in Castile in April and May.  There were also many streams.  After having taken a survey of these parts, I returned to the ship, and setting sail, discovered such a number of islands that I knew not which first to visit; the natives whom I had taken on board informed me by signs that there were so many of them that they could not be numbered; they repeated the names of more than a hundred.

I determined to steer for the largest, which is about five leagues from San Salvador [the name he gave the first island where he landed] the others were some at a greater, and some at a less distance from that island.  They are all very level, without mountains, exceedingly fertile and populous’.

 

Another island:

 

The island is verdant, level and fertile to a high degree; and I doubt not that grain is sowed and reaped the whole year round, as well as all other productions of the place.  I saw many trees, very dissimilar to those of our country, and many of them had branches of different sorts upon the same trunk; and such diversity was among them that it was the greatest wonder in the world to behold.  Thus, for instance, one branch of a tree bore leaves like those of a cane, another branch of the same tree, leaves similar to those of the lentisk.  In this manner a single tree bears five or six different kinds of fruit.

In the meantime I strayed about among the groves, which present the most enchanting sight ever witnessed, a degree of verdure prevailing like that of May in Andalusia, the trees as different from those of our country as day is from night, and the same may be said of the fruit, the weeds, the stones and everything else.

A few of the trees, however, seemed to be of a species similar to some that are to be found in Castile, though still with a great dissimilarity, but the others so unlike, that it is impossible to find any resemblance in them to those of our land.

I assure your Highnesses that these lands are the most fertile, temperate, level and beautiful countries in the world’.

 

Another island:

 

This island is the most beautiful that I have yet seen, the trees in great number, flourishing and lofty; the land is higher than the other islands, and exhibits an eminence, which though it cannot be called a mountain, yet adds a beauty to its appearance, and gives an indication of streams of water in the interior.  From this part toward the northeast is an extensive bay with many large and thick groves.  I wished to anchor there, and land, that I might examine those delightful regions, but found the coast shoal, without a possibility of casting anchor except at a distance from the shore.  The wind being favorable, I came to the Cape, which I named Hermoso, where I anchored today.

This is so beautiful a place, as well as the neighboring regions, that I know not in which course to proceed first; my eyes are never tired with viewing such delightful verdure, and of a species so new and dissimilar to that of our country, and I have no doubt there are trees and herbs here which would be of great value in Spain, as dyeing materials, medicine, spicery, etc., but I am mortified that I have no acquaintance with them.  Upon our arrival here we experienced the most sweet and delightful odor from the flowers and trees of the island.

 

The next island.

 

This island even exceeds the others in beauty and fertility.  Groves of lofty and flourishing trees are abundant, as also large lakes, surrounded and overhung by the foliage, in a most enchanting manner.  Everything looked as green as in April in Andalusia. The melody of the birds was so exquisite that one was never willing to part from the spot, and the flocks of parrots obscured the heavens.

The diversity in the appearance of the feathered tribe from those of our country is extremely curious.  A thousand different sorts of trees, with their fruit were to be met with, and of a wonderfully delicious odor.  It was a great affliction to me to be ignorant of their natures, for I am very certain they are all valuable; specimens of them and of the plants I have preserved.

Afterwards I shall set sail for another very large island which I believe to be Cipango [Japan], according to the indications I receive from the Indians on board.  They call the Island Colba, and say there are many large ships, and sailors there.  This other island they name Bosio, and inform me that it is very large; the others which lie in our course, I shall examine on the passage, and according as I find gold or spices in abundance, I shall determine what to do; at all events I am determined to proceed on to the continent, and visit the city of Guisay, where I shall deliver the letters of your Highnesses to the Great Kahn, and demand an answer, with which I shall return.

 

The reason that the height of trees and health of the forests was so unusual to him was that, in Europe and the parts of Asia and Africa where he had been, the forests had been destroyed.  The reason for this was war: 

At the time, the only way to make iron weapons was to first make enormous amounts of charcoal.  Then, you build a kiln and pour in very thin layers of crushed iron ore followed by very thick layers of charcoal.  Workers would man giant bellows to pump as much oxygen through the fire as possible, to make it as hot as they could.  Under the right conditions, it is just barely possible to get iron to ‘smelt’ out of the ore and drop to the bottom of the kiln in small amounts.  The iron could then be cast into weapons. Although iron weapons were far stronger and harder than weapons made of bronze, brass, or copper, the weapons makers could make even better weapons by turning the iron into steel.  The problem here is that it takes an enormous amount of charcoal to make even a tiny amount of steel.  (You need to heat the iron up to white hot in a charcoal kiln fed with massive amounts of oxygen through a bellows.  Then hammer it flat, heat it again, and fold it over.  Do this over and over, thousands of times and, gradually, the iron will turn into steel.)

Armies with iron weapons could defeat armies with only brass, bronze, or copper weapons. Armies with steel weapons could defeat armies with iron weapons.  The people who ran the wars wanted as much iron and steel as they could get.  But it takes an enormous amount of wood just to make a small amount of charcoal.  They cut down the forests to get this wood.  First, they cut the forests close to the iron refineries. Then they cut the ones farther away, and kept cutting and cutting.  After thousands of years of this (the iron age began about 1200 BC), the forests were basically gone.

People who wanted to build large things, like ships, needed very long logs, preferably made of hardwood.  They were incredibly rare and therefore fantastically expensive.  Columbus knew these things.  He had been given rights to take the resources from any islands he discovered and sell them, splitting the money with the king of Spain 50/50. His first priority, of course, was gold.  That was money directly: there is no need to sell it.  But the next most valuable product of the islands he discovered was lumber.  He was amazed.  There were no healthy forests in his homeland.  Here, they were everywhere.

In his book ‘The Devastation of the Indies,’ the historian Bartolomé de Las Casas describes what happened to these formerly beautiful islands after the Europeans arrived in great detail.  The Europeans began to take everything of value, without any regard whatsoever for the health of the land. 

As the name of Las Casas’ book implies, they left nothing but devastation. 

Columbus eventually ended up on the island that he thought was the most beautiful of all, the ‘terrestrial paradise’ (as he called it) that the natives called ‘Haiti.

In the native language, this means ‘the mountainous island.’  When Columbus returned to Haiti in 1493, he brought armies of loggers to cut the forests and charcoal makers to turn the lumber into charcoal.  They worked so rapidly that, within two decades, the land was (to use Las Casas word) ‘devastated.’   But the healthy forests didn’t just make the island beautiful.  Torrential rains and massive storms that the natives called ‘Hurricane’ hit the island on a regular basis.  As long as the forests where there, the roots held the soil in place.  When the forests were gone, the rains washed everything away.  Massive landslides pulled entire mountainsides down across the plains.

The rains in the mountains that used to soak into the soil now bounced off of the rocks and poured down the slopes like tidal waves, sweeping everything in its path down the hills.  Stagnant pools of water bred bacteria that spread disease. 

Earthquakes are common in Haiti.  If the forests on the mountains were healthy, people got shook up, but there was little damage.  With the forests and soil gone, the shaking sent giant boulders down the mountains killing everyone in their way.  Each time a boulder hit it shook loose a dozen more and rockslides took out everything in their path.  What would have been a minor annoyance while the land was healthy was now a serious disaster that could kill millions of people. 

Columbus called Haiti ‘terrestrial paradise.’  When he arrived, it looked what he imagined that heaven would look like. It had been under the care of people with natural law societies for thousands of years.  They kept it healthy. 

What happened to this land after people with the different society conquered it? Here is a description from 2010:

 

"If you want to put the worst case scenario together in the Western hemisphere it’s Haiti," said Richard Olson, a professor at Florida International University who directs the Disaster Risk Reduction in the Americas project.

The list of catastrophes is mind-numbing: this week’s devastating earthquake. Four tropical storms or hurricanes that killed about 800 people in 2008.  Killer storms in 2005 and 2004.  Floods in 2007, 2006, 2003 (twice) and 2002.  And that’s just the 21st Century run-down. 

“There’s a whole bunch of things working against Haiti.  One is the hurricane track.  The second is tectonics.  Then you have the environmental degradation and the poverty,” he said.  This [the 2010 earthquake] is the 15th disaster since 2001 in which the U.S.  Agency for International Development has sent money and help to Haiti.  Some 3,000 people have been killed and millions of people displaced in the disasters that preceded this week’s earthquake.

This week’s devastating quake comes as Haiti is still trying to recover from 2008, when it was hit four times by tropical storms and hurricanes, said Kathleen Tierney, director of the University of Colorado’s Natural Hazard Center.  Every factor that disaster experts look for in terms of vulnerability is the worst it can be for Haiti, said Dennis Mileti, a seismic safety commissioner for the state of California and author of the book Disasters by Design. "It doesn’t get any worse," said Mileti, a retired University of Colorado professor. "I fear this may go down in history as the largest disaster ever, or pretty close to it.".

For this to be the deadliest disaster on record, the death toll will have to top the 2004 Asian tsunami that killed more than 227,000 and a 1976 earthquake in China that killed 255,000, according to the U.S.  Geological Survey.

While nobody knows the death toll in Haiti, a leading senator, Youri Latortue, told The Associated Press that as many as 500,000 could be dead.

"This was not that huge of an earthquake, but there’s been a lot of damage," he said.  "It’s the tragedy of a natural disaster superimposed on a poor country.".

 

The above passage was written in 2010, a long time ago in terms of environment disasters in the devastated lands of the Caribbean.  Since then, things have only gotten worse.  If you look on today’s news, you will almost certainly find something catastrophic that happened in the last few weeks, killing thousands, tens of thousands, or hundreds of thousands of people.  And there is no hope on the horizon.  The type of society that now controls the land can’t function if it doesn’t have enough jobs so that everyone who doesn’t have an outside income can get one.  The only way to create jobs is to turn a blind eye to the destruction caused by the job creators.  Mining companies can still take out metals profitably as long as they don’t have to worry about releases of cyanide, mercury, arsenic, and other toxic materials they use.  If the government doesn’t regulate these things, the companies can mind there, rather than in other countries, and they will have more jobs.  Many companies on the mainland produce dioxins and other poisons that never break down and are so deadly the companies have been banned entirely:  the companies have been told they can’t operate on the mainland anymore.  There are a lot of impoverished islands in the Caribbean that want these ‘job creators’ to move there.  Perhaps, with the with the right amount in grants, Haiti will win this competition and the companies will build their facilities there. 

In 1492, Columbus called Haiti ‘terrestrial paradise,’ an image of what heaven must look like.  By 1542, when Las Casas wrote about it, it could have been used as an example to help people see what hell must look like.  Now? Well, if you are brave enough to go there (and few people are; it is considered one of the most dangerous places on earth), you will find it is even worse.

History

Historians who try to estimate populations from pre-conquest times generally come up with very low numbers until immediately before the first Europeans arrived.  There were a lot of people there when the Europeans arrived:  this is undeniable.  But there couldn’t have been a lot of people before this.  We know this because, when large numbers of people live in an area for a long time, they destroy it.  People couldn’t have lived in the Americas in large numbers for very long, because we don’t see the destruction. 

For a long time, this simple argument was accepted.  There were a lot of people in the Caribbean, Mexico, and the Southeastern part of North America when the first Europeans arrived.  But these people were recent arrivals.  Go back a few hundred years, and the population had to have been zero, so close to zero that we can basically ignore it. 

But modern tools are showing that this simply wasn’t true.  Humans lived in the Americas for more than 10,000 years. Humans, like other animals, have sexual desires.  They have sex and this leads to babies.  If there is no birth control, and food is plentiful, populations increase.  With four children that live to sexual maturity per couple, they double ever 25 years.  How is it possible to have a population of few thousand people that remains stable for 10,000 years?  The people would have to not have sex.  They would have to have not fed their crying babies.  Animals that don’t have sex and/or don’t feed their babies go extinct very quickly.  There is no natural force that can keep populations steady for even hundreds of years, let alone thousands. 

Each decade, as technology advances, the evidence shows that the population had to be much higher than the estimates a decade before.  At first, it was 45 million (close to the figures for the parts of the Americas the Europeans first encountered, before European plagues arrived; for this to be the total population, the parts of the Americas where the Europeans didn’t arrive immediately would have had to have been vacant.)   It kept going up and is now at hundreds of millions.  How many hundreds of millions?  Now, the population of the Americas is about 900 million. 

We can find evidence that the pre-conquest American people went to great lengths to keep their environment healthy in many places.  But the most obvious evidence is the fact that hundreds of millions of people lived on these continents for thousands of years without destroying it.

When I talk to people about the state of the environment, I get nothing but depression. They say, almost universally, that we are doomed.  It is not possible, they say, for large numbers of people to live in an area for any reasonable period of time without destroying the land and making it uninhabitable.  This is a truism that they accept as if it is a self-evident fact, not worth taking the time to prove because there is no possible way it can’t be true.  Since it is impossible for us to survive, there is no point in trying.  Why waste time doing the impossible?

But history tells us it is not impossible.  Other people did it.  Why can’t we?

Seattle Quote

The quote below shows how a person born and raised in a system like this might look at the world around them and might view people they see who treated the world differently.  It comes from a letter by Chief Seattle to the Duwamish to William Medill, the head of the Indian Affairs Department, a division of the Department of War of the United States of America. 

Medill worked for the Department of War of the United States government.  Medill reported directly to James Polk, the President.  Polk was an expansionist: he believed in a principle called ‘manifest destiny,’ which holds that the creator of this planet had a destiny in mind for each part of it.  The creator made this destiny ‘manifest,’ or obvious to the people, by granting the people he wanted to have each part military superiority and then manipulating the battles so that the side he wanted to have the land won the battles and gained control of the land.  The creator he believed in, God, had given the United States the largest and most powerful military the world had ever known and surrounded the United States with land populated by people with very limited abilities to defend the land where they lived.  Polk believed this indicated that it was God’s plan that the United States take control of this land.  He wanted to go to heaven.  He couldn’t do this if he didn’t do what God required him to do.  He would have to take this land.

He had ordered Medil to remove the people who lived in the areas United States corporations wanted to use to set up their operations.  People lived there.  Medil had the authority to use military force to remove the people around the Puget sound, but his armies were already stretched thin and didn’t want to have to do this.  He sent in negotiators to try to get the people to move voluntarily.

They presented their standard offer:  they had identified certain land they would set aside for the ‘Indians.’  This was land that the United States government had determined didn’t have any significant resources and wasn’t very productive farmland, so the corporations and farmers of America wouldn’t put pressure on the government to make it available.  The people who lived around the Puget Sound could move to these places. If they agreed to move voluntarily, the government would grant them safe passage and provide them with food and supplies on the trip.  When they arrived, the government would give them money.  The negotiators framed their proposal in a way that seemed strange to the Duwamish:  they were offering to buy the land from the people.  The leaders of the people in the Puget Sound knew that the United States had a massive army with equipment and weapons far beyond the means of the Duwamish.  The United States could destroy them.  They knew that, if they rejected the offer outright, this would happen.  They not just lose their homes, they would die horrible deaths at the hands of the conquerors. 

The Americans had been negotiating with a leader named Chief Seattle.  When he got the offer, he took it to the leaders of the various villages and towns in the area.  The different groups had meetings to discuss the response and drafted a response to send to Medill.  The passages below are from the response:

 

How can you buy or sell the sky, the warmth of the land? The idea is strange to us. If we do not own the freshness of the air and the sparkle of the water, how can you buy them?

Every part of this earth is sacred to my people. Every shining pine needle, every sandy shore, every mist in the dark woods, every clearing and humming insect is holy in the memory and experience of my people. The sap which courses through the trees carries the memories of the red man.

The white man's dead forget the country of their birth when they go to walk among the stars. Our dead never forget this beautiful earth, for it is the mother of the red man. We are part of the earth and it is part of us. The perfumed flowers are our sisters; the deer, the horse, the great eagle, these are our brothers. The rocky crests, the juices in the meadows, the body heat of the pony, and man—all belong to the same family.

So, when the Great Chief in Washington sends word that he wishes to buy our land, he asks much of us. The Great Chief sends word he will reserve us a place so that we can live comfortably to ourselves. He will be our father and we will be his children.  So, we will consider your offer to buy our land. But it will not be easy. For this land is sacred to us. This shining water that moves in the streams and rivers is not just water but the blood of our ancestors. If we sell you the land, you must remember that it is sacred, and you must teach your children that it is sacred and that each ghostly reflection in the clear water of the lakes tells of events and memories in the life of my people. The water's murmur is the voice of my father's father.

The rivers are our brothers, they quench our thirst. The rivers carry our canoes, and feed our children. If we sell you our land, you must remember, and teach your children, that the rivers are our brothers and yours, and you must henceforth give the rivers the kindness you would give any brother.

We know that the white man does not understand our ways. One portion of land is the same to him as the next, for he is a stranger who comes in the night and takes from the land whatever he needs. The earth is not his brother, but his enemy, and when he has conquered it, he moves on. He leaves his father's grave behind, and he does not care. He kidnaps the earth from his children, and he does not care. His father's grave, and his children's birthright are forgotten. He treats his mother, the earth, and his brother, the sky, as things to be bought, plundered, sold like sheep or bright beads. His appetite will devour the earth and leave behind only a desert.

This we know; the earth does not belong to man; man belongs to the earth. This we know. All things are connected like the blood which unites one family. All things are connected.  Even the white man, whose God walks and talks with him as friend to friend, cannot be exempt from the common destiny. We may be brothers after all. We shall see. One thing we know which the white man may one day discover; our God is the same God.

You may think that you own Him as you wish to own our land; but you cannot. He is the God of man, and His compassion is equal for the red man and the white. The earth is precious to Him, and to harm the earth is to heap contempt on its creator. The whites too shall pass; perhaps sooner than all other tribes. Contaminate your bed and you will one night suffocate in your own waste.

But in your perishing you will shine brightly fired by the strength of the God who brought you to this land and for some special purpose gave you dominion over this land and over the red man.

That destiny is a mystery to us, for we do not understand when the buffalo are all slaughtered, the wild horses are tamed, the secret corners of the forest heavy with the scent of many men and the view of the ripe hills blotted by talking wires. That is the end of living and the beginning of survival.

Humankind has not woven the web of life. We are but one thread within it. Whatever we do to the web, we do to ourselves. All things are bound together. All things connect.  Man does not weave this web of life. He is merely a strand of it. Whatever he does to the web, he does to himself.

 

You and I and other people who live in territorial sovereignty societies are so used to destruction we take it for granted.  We see it as natural and simply a part of the way existence works.

But it isn’t.  When I read Seattle’s letter, I can’t help but put myself in his place, mentally, and think about what these people must have thought the first time they saw people clear-cutting forests, stretching nets across rivers to take every single fish, or using tons of cyanide and other toxic chemicals to extract a few tiny flakes of gold.  How could they even believe such a thing could be possible?

Social and Personal Responsibility Incentives

Natural law societies and territorial sovereignty societies work in different ways, creating different incentives.   Some of the most important incentives involve the forces pushing people to get along with others.

Territorial sovereignty societies give massive rewards conquerors.  The group that conquers land becomes its sovereign owner.  Everything on the land belongs to them.  Everything under the land, from the imaginary lines that mark the borders of their conquered territory in a pie-shaped wedge to the center of the earth belongs to them.   Everything the land produces now belongs to them. Everything that the land will ever produce until the end of time belongs to them.  These are the rewards the territorial sovereignty societies offer for the most violent and inhumane behaviors within the capabilities of human beings. 

People intent on conquest can use promises to share the benefits of conquest to induce others to help them.  They can tell directors of corporations that if the corporations help them, they will give some of the land they take to the corporations or sell it at a ridiculous price that is far less than they would have had to pay for similar land.  They can post notices all around the world promising to give land to any soldiers that join the military and then follow the orders of their commander, knowing that they will be ordered to kill large numbers of people and inflict unimaginable misery on people who have done nothing to deserve this misery. 

They can use the income they get from prior conquests to pay people to make weapons for their next conquest.  If they have been very successful, they may set up extremely large organizations, with millions of people who come to work and spend more than ¾ of their waking hours doing nothing but helping provide supplies to build tools needed to commit the most brutal acts imaginable.  They can use part of the wealth they get from conquest to hire trainers to put young men under conditions of great stress so they can’t really understand what they are doing, and then train them to kill on command, without a second thought, and follow orders that, if followed, will clearly get them crippled, driven insane, or killed. 

The people who gain most from conquest can use part of the wealth they get to create massive organizational structures dedicated to efficient, well organized, and remorseless mass murder and destruction. 

We might think of ‘social responsibility’ as ‘acting in a way that promotes a safe, orderly, and peaceful world for the other members of the human race.’  It is hard to think of anything that is more socially irresponsible than the behaviors that the societies we inherited reward.

We might think of ‘personal responsibility’ as ‘dealing responsibly with others in your personal relationships.’  Everyone who has ever lived in a territorial sovereignty society knows about crime. It is everywhere.  The great majority of the people in all territorial sovereignty societies are in a category called the ‘working class.’ These people have no right to share in the bounty of the land and, generally speaking, get nothing at all unless they work.  If there aren’t enough jobs for everyone, some people are not going to eat.  (You might take a job away from someone by offering to work for less, but that doesn’t mean there are now enough jobs for all:  Just as many people are unemployed as before.)  Some people are not going to stay alive if they act responsibly and honestly.  The reward for crime is the right to remain alive and get enough to eat for a short while.  Territorial sovereignty societies work in ways that not only reward socially irresponsible behaviors, they punish social responsibility, often with death. 

Natural law societies have entirely different incentive structures because of the way they distribute the basic productivity that represents the bounty of the land.  Our group in Pastland has created a natural law society.  No country exists to make rules about the bounty.  No owners have any rights to decide what to do with it.  If we had countries or owners, we (as a group) wouldn’t have to worry about deciding what to do with the bounty of the world.  The country or owner would have rules for this. We wouldn’t be involved.

But since we don’t accept that either countries or individuals can own land, there are no rules in place.  We have no choice.  We have to have meetings and divide the bounty of the land somehow.  This leads to some very understandable relationships that tie the rights to get wealth to both personal and social responsibility.

Personal Responsibility in Natural law societies

If no one owns the land, no one owns the things it produces.  If the land produces rice, no one owns that rice. The group must have meetings of some sort and make decisions about what to do with this rice.

In our case in Pastland, we sell this rice (trade it for money).  We then divide the rice by dividing the money.  We would be very foolish not to reward the people who went out of their way making sure the land was seeded, and making sure the rice got collected at the right time and brought into storage.  If they don’t do these things, we get nothing and we all starve.  We must pay them, not because they demand it, but because we need to create incentives for them to step forward in the future. 

The amount we pay depends on market forces.  If we overpay, more people will volunteer for the work than can take the available jobs.  People will compete to get the right to work by offering to work for less than the prevailing rate.  We will accept their offers of course:  any money we save on production costs goes directly into our own pockets.  In time, of course, we will learn what it takes to make sure enough people show up to do the work when it has to be done. 

In our case, we wind up paying $700,000 a year for workers and $50,000 a year for the person who organizes everything and the people she needs to help with organizational tasks.  We pay a total of $750,000 a year.  This leaves $2.4 million, the ‘free cash flow’ of the land.  You could think of this as a gift from nature.  It will go somewhere but the people who get it will not get it in exchange for anything they do in production; they will get it for free.

So far, we have been assuming we divide the bounty of the land the simplest possible way: everyone gets an equal share. 

But we don’t have to do this. 

What if people do things that bother the great majority?

They aren’t ‘crimes,’ per se, as we haven’t drawn up a long list of books describing of every single act that might bother anyone in minute detail.  There are a lot of things people can do that can bother others.  We might not try to write them all down and describe them.  People will still know that these things bother others. 

 Some people like to stay up late and listen to music or watch TV.  If walls are thin, this can bother their neighbors.  Some parents ignore their children and don’t keep them from bothering the people they see around them.  Some people smoke upwind of non-smokers, or swear in inappropriate places. Some people keep doing things that bother others even after they have been told it bothers others and been asked to stop. 

In territorial sovereignty societies, there really isn’t anything the people who are bothered can do about this.  If it isn’t illegal, the police won’t do anything about it.  (My neighbor has a lot of dogs and beats them. I hear him getting angry and screaming at them.  I hear the sound of him beating them and then I hear them howling in pain.  I have called the police.  I live in a remote area with very limited facilities. They say that the law really isn’t very clear on this issue.  It will be a very hard case for them, if they get involved, and they aren’t sure they can win.  They would rather not try. There is nothing I can do.) 

Natural law societies are different. 

Our group in Pastland collects the gifts the land provides to the human race.  We then divide these gifts the way we agree is best.  There is no requirement that we give everyone the same gift.  If people do things that bother others, the people who have been bothered can raise the issue at a meting.  We don’t have to have a written law against whatever they did to send them a message. We don’t have to ‘take anything away from them’ to make it clear we don’t like the way they are acting, and we certainly don’t have to put them in jail.  We were going to give them a large gift. Everyone who was responsible will get a large gift.  But the people we have doubts about—the people who haven’t proven to use that they are responsible—will get less.

We don’t have to prove that they did something wrong.  In fact, they may not actually do anything wrong at all.  It is enough that we think they might be doing things we don’t want to be done.  We can make it clear, by the way we divide the gifts the world gives us, that we need people to do more than just ‘not do anything that is obviously irresponsible.’ We need them to act in ways that make everyone around them believe that they are responsible. 

If someone loses her temper and causes trouble, even once, she is going to have to win her back into our good graces.  This may take months.  It may take years. But she is going to have to show that she has her temper under control. If she succeeds, she will be back with the other people who have reputations for honesty.  If she fails, we aren’t actually punishing her, we just aren’t giving her the same rewards we give to people who have proven they are responsible.

The concept might be easier to understand if you realize that most natural law societies distributed wealth in parties.  When they had a successful hunt, there was a feast and celebration.  After taping maple trees for syrup, some people would make candy and there would be music, drink, and confections.  Every harvest had is festival and people who had helped got their rewards.  People who cause problems don’t have to be ‘punished.’  All we have to do is not invite them to the feasts and celebrations.  We eat.  They go hungry.  They will learn.

We would expect people in natural law societies to not reward people who are irresponsible. We can put this another way:  they are rewarding responsibility.  In Pastland, we give out the rewards in money.  We pay people to be responsible.  Everyone who is responsible will get money. People who are not responsible will not get the same amount of money.  People who do things that are extremely irresponsible, say stealing, getting into violent fights, or forcing others into sex, may be cut off entirely.

In territorial sovereignty societies, if people commit crimes and get caught, they are put in jail.  In jail, they have a safe place to sleep, enough to eat, and at least basic health care. Often, people in territorial sovereignty societies have better lives in jail than they had on the outside.  Many people who go to jail and get released commit new crimes almost immediately so they can be put back into the only home they know.

In natural law societies, acts that harm others always have negative consequences.  If you are used to getting $2,000 a year as your income from the bounty of the land, and now find you are only going to get $1,000, you will realize your life is no longer as good as it would have been if you had been able to get the same reputation for responsibility as the other people in the group.  It is real pain.

Social And Environmental Responsibility Examples In Real Territorial Sovereignty Societies

When people from territorial sovereignty societies first arrived in natural law societies, they were astounded by the behavior of the natives.  They had no experience with people who seemed to be naturally honest and caring.

You can clearly read the surprise they felt in their writings.  This is from the very first encounter that Columbus had with the people of the first inhabited island he found:

 

They are very gentile and without knowledge of what is evil, nor do they murder or steal.  Your highness may believe that in all the world there can be no better or gentler people.  All the people show the most singular loving behavior and they speak pleasantly.  I assure Your Highnesses that I believe than in all the world there is no better people nor better country.  They love their neighbors as themselves and they have the sweetest talking the world and are gentle and always laughing.

 

The most prolific writer of the period, Bartolomé de Las Casas, described them this way:

 

All the land so far discovered is a beehive of people; it is as though God had crowded into these lands the great majority of mankind.  And of all the infinite universe of humanity, these people are the most devoid of wickedness and duplicity.  They are by nature the most humble, patient, and peaceable, holding no grudges, free from embroilments, neither excitable nor quarrelsome.  These people are the most devoid of rancors, hatreds, or desire for vengeance of any people in the world.

They possess little and have no desire to possess worldly goods.  For this reason they are not arrogant, embittered, or greedy.  They are very clean in their persons, with alert, intelligent minds.  Some of the secular Spaniards who have been here for many years say that the goodness of the Indians is undeniable.

 

The official historian of the Spanish Crown during the time that Columbus was alive was a Dutchman named ‘Peter Myrtar.’ Myrtar was very impressed by the honesty of the people of the lands he studied.  He studied the people and came to the conclusion that there is something about the idea of sharing the land and the things the land produced that led to this behavior.  Here are some quotes from his official report on the people of the new world, called ‘Orbo Novo’ (The New World), describing the people on the island of Haiti:

 

It is proven that amongst them the land belongs to everybody, just as does the sun or the water.  They know no difference between meum and tuum, that source of all evils.  It requires so little to satisfy them, that in that vast region there is always more land to cultivate than is needed. It is indeed a golden age, neither ditches, nor hedges, nor walls to enclose their domains; they live in gardens open to all, without laws and without judges; their conduct is naturally equitable, and whoever injures his neighbor is considered a criminal and an outlaw.

 

He goes on:

 

They know neither weights nor measures, nor that source of all misfortunes, money; living in a golden age, without laws, without lying judges, without books, satisfied with their life, and in no wise solicitous for the future.

First Contact

Columbus left his personal papers, including the logs of his 1492 voyage, to the historian Bartolomé de las Casas.   Las Casas reproduced these papers in a multi-volume work called ‘Historia de Las Indies.’ 

This book was banned shortly after it was published. The authorities considered many of the passages of this book to be dangerous and harmful to the war effort and morale of both the troops and people at home paying for the wars. (They wanted to conquer the land and take its wealth; the inhabitants were in the way and they wanted them removed. Any literature that humanized the inhabitants or made them seem worthy of empathy was dangerous.) 

The ban was in place for five centuries; it was finally removed on June14, 1966.  People could now legally read original records of this period, written by people who were actually there and wrote about the things they saw the same day they saw them. But that doesn’t mean this information immediately became available.  Most of the banned books had been kept in secret:  While the books were banned, the authorities could and did execute any people found with them, often through public torture.  Obviously, there weren’t a lot of records that showed where they books were located and now to find them.  These books only really became accessible in the 2000s, when researchers began taking scanners into the archives; they scanned everything, digitized it, and then indexed it so it could be searched. People who wanted to understand what actually happened could finally do so. 

I encourage anyone interested in what really happened to read the actual records of the events written by people who were there. The logs that Columbus kept tell us a lot about the clash that took place between these two entirely different cultures.  We, living in the far distant future, don’t know what really happened.  The authorities didn’t really want people to know what happened (otherwise, they wouldn’t have felt they had to ban the records).  There are thousands of books and other documents that have been banned, hidden, or distorted that can help us understand how events in the past really unfolded and how the world came to work as it does.

Here, I want to just focus on the issue of social and personal responsibility, so we can see the differences in the two different societies that have existed in human history. 

Columbus had many occasions to witness the honesty of the people of Haiti and the other Caribbean islands.  One such occasion was Christmas day, 1492.  Columbus had been able to let the natives know certain day, the 25th of December, was a very important to his people.  The people of one town in Haiti decided to take advantage of this to organize a party.  They put together a massive feast and celebration to be held on Christmas. A man named ‘Guanahani,’ who Columbus referred to as ‘the king’ in his records, had invited Columbus to be his personal guest at this festival.  Columbus had accepted the invitation.

Columbus had three ships, two tiny, highly maneuverable ‘caravels,’ the Nina and Pinta, and an extremely large and heavy supply ship, the Santa Maria.  Columbus had taken command of the large ship.  Three days before Christmas, he began making his way to the town that had issued the invitation.  He had not planned his time well and knew he wouldn’t make it on time unless he hurried. By the time of nightfall of Christmas Eve, he was still far away and decided to take the risk of running at night, so he could be there on time.  

This was dangerous because the waters around Haiti have many reefs, sandbars, and rocks that could damage the ship.  Shortly after midnight, he ran the ship on a reef. It was stuck.  He couldn’t get it off.  (If you read his logs, you will see that Columbus was an arrogant man who wanted to take credit for everything good that happened and wouldn’t take responsibility for anything bad.  He came up with a long story to blame the wreck on a cabin boy and the watch captain who disobeyed standing orders to let the cabin boy take charge.  But he was in charge.  If the ship wrecked, in my opinion, he was responsible for it.) The ship had all of the provisions for the expedition.  He tried to save it by having everything thrown overboard that wasn’t nailed down, in the hope this would lighten the ship and they could float it off the reef, but this didn’t work and the ship sank. 

He then did a lot of different things that he describes in his logs.  One was to send a man ahead to tell Guanahani that he wouldn’t be able to make Christmas dinner as he had promised.  He wasn’t asking for  help, he just wanted to let his host know that he wouldn’t be there.  Here is what happened next, from the logs:

 

I sent boat to shore to inform the king, who had invited the ships to come on the previous Saturday. His town was about a league and a half from the reef.  They reported that he wept when he heard the news, and he sent all his people with large canoes to unload the ship. This was done, and they landed all there was between decks in a very short time.

Such was the great promptitude and diligence shown by that king.

He himself, with brothers and relations, were actively assisting as well in the ship as in the care of the property when it was landed, that all might be properly guarded.

The king and all his people wept. They are a loving people, without covetousness, and fit for anything, and I assure your Highnesses that there is no better land nor people. They love their neighbors as themselves, and their speech is the sweetest and gentlest in the world, and always with a smile. Your Highnesses should believe that they have very good customs among themselves.  The king is a man of remarkable presence, and with a certain self-contained manner that is a pleasure to see. They have good memories, wish to see everything, and ask the use of what they see.

 

Here is the log entry for the next day:

 

Today, at sunrise, Guanahani came to the caravel Nina, where the Admiral was, and said to him, almost weeping, that he need not be sorry, for that he would give him all he had; that he had placed two large houses at the disposal of the Christians who were on shore, and that he would give more if they were required, and as many canoes as could load from the ship and discharge on shore, with as many people as were wanted. 

Of all that there was on board the ship, not a needle, nor a board, nor a nail was lost, for she remained as whole as when she sailed, except that it was necessary to cut away in order to get out the jars and merchandise, which were landed and carefully guarded.  So honest are they without any covetousness for the goods of others, and so above all was that virtuous king.

 

All of the goods of their supply ship had been scattered to the sea.  The ship itself had been torn to pieces on the reef.  The natives arrived with large numbers of divers.  These divers scoured the sea.  They collected everything from the ship.  All the broken boards, all the nails.  They had had to break open some of the cabinets to remove the things inside but all the contents, together with the boards and nails, had been collected.  

They brought these items to town and stored them outside, while they had several people empty their homes of their personal items, so that the items from the ship could be stored in these buildings. Hundreds of people had access to these items.  Any of them could have secreted something away.  If this had happened in Lisbon or Palos, Columbus wouldn’t have expected to recover anything:  people would take everything, starting with the most valuable items.  But on Haiti, this didn’t happen.  In many places in the logs, Columbus describes how badly the natives wanted the things the ship carried.  They would trade family treasures made of solid gold (something they quickly realized Columbus valued) for trinkets like the little brass bells called ‘hawks bells.’ They wanted these items, but only if they could get them honestly. 

Perhaps, in Lisbon or Palos, there would be some people who would feel bound to return at least some of the things they collected.  Some people would return everything and not even ask for a reward. But the people of Haiti appeared to all be honest.  How could such a thing happen?

If we understand the incentive system, and realize that incentives really do matter, this makes sense.  The system they live in naturally rewards responsibility.  People are paid (if they use money) to act in responsible ways. They can get far more by being honest than by being dishonest.  They grow up with this reality.  It is a part of their lives from birth.  The people around them are honest.  They see this every day.  They would not see this as a result of cultural conditioning due to the inherent reward systems of their society.  To them, this is just the way human beings act.

Back to the Future

How about today?  Is there something about the island that makes anyone who lives there incredibly honest and responsible? People who run the United States government’s travel department collect data about the different places government employees may travel and present information to help them prepare for their trip.  The quote below is from the site, referring to the people of the same island today:

 

Reconsider travel to Haiti due to crime and civil unrest.  Violent crime, such as armed robbery, is common.  Protests, tire burning, and road blockages are frequent and often spontaneous.  Local police may lack the resources to respond effectively to serious criminal incidents, and emergency response, including ambulance service, is limited or non-existent.

Travelers are sometimes targeted, followed, and violently attacked and robbed shortly after leaving the Port-au-Prince international airport.  The U.S.  Embassy requires its personnel to use official transportation to and from the airport, and it takes steps to detect surveillance and deter criminal attacks during these transports.

The U.S. government has limited ability to provide emergency services to U.S. citizens in some areas of Haiti.  The Embassy discourages its personnel from walking in most neighborhoods.  The Embassy prohibits its personnel from:

Visiting establishments after dark without secure, on-site parking.

Using any kind of public transportation or taxis.

Visiting banks and using ATMs.

Driving outside of Port-au-Prince at night.

Traveling anywhere between 1:00 a.m.  and 5:00 a.m..

Visiting certain parts of the city at any time without prior approval and special security measures in place.

If you decide to travel to Haiti:

Avoid demonstrations.

Arrange airport transfers and hotels in advance, or have your host meet you upon arrival.

Be careful about providing your destination address in Haiti.  Do not provide personal information to unauthorized individuals located in the immigration, customs, or other areas inside or near any airports in Haiti.

As you leave the airport, make sure you are not being followed.  If you notice you are being followed, drive to the nearest police station immediately.

Do not physically resist any robbery attempt.

 

Shortly after Columbus arrived, the newcomers began destroying the societies that had been there for thousands of years.  They were raised in entirely different societies that worked entirely differently.  They wanted to get rid of the societies that were there and replace them with those built on the principles they understood.  They seemed to have succeeded. 

Social Responsibility

‘Personal responsibility’ means being responsible in your dealings with others on an individual level. 

‘Social responsibility’ means help to create a better society. 

It is hard to imagine anything that is more socially irresponsible than this:

Imagine you are a member of a peaceful and generally responsible group.  You see there is wealth that is shared among the people and want it for yourself.  You can’t take it personally, because you can’t overcome everyone else to take it.  But you can find ways to create a gang and somehow convince them that they are entitled in some way and for some reason to the wealth.  It is theirs and they have a right to take it.  You will lead them and help them.  It will be hard, but if they succeed, they will have something that is rightfully theirs, and the people who get it now (who are not entitled) will not get it. 

You might try telling them something like this:  They won’t be ‘members of a gang’ they will be ‘founders of a nation.’  You may hire someone to come up with a glorious sounding piece of music to be a ‘national anthem.’    You may hire someone to sew some cloth into a special pattern and call it a ‘flag.’  You might draw up a document that says that your nation stands for wonderful principles and expresses high sounding ideals that, by implication, the others around you don’t care about.  The people of this nation are not independent.  Other people who are not citizens of the nation are sharing the wealth of the land that has been properly claimed by and therefore belongs to the nation.  The people of the nation are not free:  they don’t have the right to determine what happens to the wealth of their nation without interference.  Freedom and independence are not given, they have to be taken.  If the people of the nation don’t fight for these things, they don’t deserve anything at all.  You can hire professionals to write stories about the horrible things that the people who hate the country and want to deny it rights are doing.  You can call them tyrants, villains, demons, devils, and monsters.  You can make up and spread stories that they do horrible things, like terrorize ‘their own people’ and kill and eat babies. 

The people who start wars in our world today spend months or years preparing people for the wars.  They need people to have a certain mindset. There are a lot of books that explain how to create this mindset.  It is not an art, it is a science.  You can learn this science in school.  Follow the procedures, go from step to step, and pretty soon people’s minds will be prepared.  They will be itching for war, anxious for it, craving it, ready to fight anyone who says the war is a bad idea or tries to use reason to combat the hatred.

This sounds like a truly horrible thing for anyone to do and if you want an example of ‘the most extreme kind of social irresponsibility possible’ you probably couldn’t find anything more extreme than this.

Now think back about your schooling. Some group of people created the ‘curriculum’ (the general guidelines for the educational process).  Who was in charge of this group?  (Was it the same organization that organizes for war?)

You and I were raised in a crazy world. 

The schools in our world today teach children that their highest allegiance is not to the human race (we don’t pledge allegiance to the human race) or to their planet, or to nature and its wondrous gifts.  Their highest allegiance is to an entity called a ‘country.’ 

What exactly is a ‘country?’ 

Why are children required to pledge their allegiance to it?  

Children are told that their country is a wonderful thing with qualities that sound too good to be true, like liberty and justice for all.  Is this really true?  In countries that make this claim, is it really true that no one has ever been subjected to injustice or treated unfairly?  (Is there ‘justice for all’?) No one has been put into prison, forced to work to get the necessities of life, conscripted into military service, or otherwise deprived of their liberty, ever, under any circumstances? If it does not do this, what is the logic behind having children openly claim it does?  Is this done to make the world a better place and to improve conditions of existence for the human race?  Or is there some other purpose?

What about telling children lies that are called ‘history lessons?’  What is the purpose of this?  Why did the leaders of the societies in power ban actual records of events regarding the clash of societies that took place 500 years ago? Was this to make the world better for everyone?  Or were they trying to manipulate the way children thought and keep truths from them that would make it harder to create this mindset? 

Social and environmental responsibility in natural law societies

Our group in Pastland has passed a moratorium. 

The majority of our group—which is the majority of the human race—has decided we don’t want any human entities owning any part of the world, at least not right away.  A few people don’t like this moratorium and voted against it. But after the vote, the chairperson talked to these people.  She said ‘the majority has ruled; are you going to respect the will of the majority or are you going to try fight to get rights to this land for yourself or a country?’  Most were willing to accept the will of the majority.  Two people said they were not willing to accept:  they were raised and educated to believe they had a responsibility to put the interests of their country above everything else.  The country was more important than life itself.  They would not agree to stop fighting for rights for their country.’

She told them that, if they want the benefits of living with a group of people, they have to make certain concessions. They have just announced that they will use violence to make sure the majority will not get the things the majority wants.  We can’t let someone who is going to use violence against the majority to live with us.  If you can’t agree you will follow accept the rule we made (a simple one, the moratorium) you will have to leave.  The two people who had said that they refused to honor the moratorium thought about this and realized that the benefits of living with an organized group, working together, were far greater than the benefits of having the right to organize for violence against the majority (of the human race) to try to gain some advantage over others. 

Territorial sovereignty societies rest on a certain foundation:  Each self-defined group of people in the world can stake out a certain part of the world and call it their sovereign territory or ‘nation.’  They can then use any means necessary, including organized mass murder, to make sure no one interferes in their claimed rights.  These societies are built on social irresponsibility.  They can’t really exist without it:  It is true that some countries may have peace and responsible leaders for a time, but it will always be possible for a person to take over a country and use its wealth for things that harm the people of the world as a whole. If we think of ‘the society on earth’ as a single entity, it always be possible for someone to harm it.

Our simple natural law society in Pastland includes all members of the human race.  Everyone in it has agreed they will not take any steps to try to use force to overthrow the will of the majority of the members of the human race. They have accepted this is the prime directive of our race and nothing is more important to us than protecting this prime directive.  Anyone who violates this can’t live with us.  We will do anything and take anystepsnecessary to make sure any attempt to use force to override our directives does not succeed. 

We have to do this.  We have no choice.  If we ever allow people to get away with using force to prevent override the will of the majority we (referring to the human race as a whole) lose all ability to do anything collectively as a group.  Nothing we want (where ‘we’ means ‘the people of the earth’) matters.  We become helpless.  This is why our prime directive has to be to make sure that no one ever has the ability to overcome the mandate of the majority.  This has to be there to support anything else we do. 

National law societies have a characteristic that makes it very hard for small groups of people to gain control of enough resources to force undesirable change on the group as a whole: they use direct democracy to determine what happens to the most important flow of wealth, the bounty of the land.

Our group in Pastland provides a good example.  After we pay the people who do things in production, we have $2.4 million in cash on the table.  We have meetings and elections to determine what happens to it.  We use it for whatever we want.   If people want more of it, they have to convince us to let them have it.  If they try to take it, by force, they will not be able to do this because they will never be able to match the resources of the defenders.  If people try to use force to get more of this wealth than an equal share, we can cut them off entirely and not even give them an equal share. We can give them nothing at all. Then, they have no hope at all:

A small group with no resources can never defeat a large group with enormous resources.  People realize this.  They know they are not going to win, so they won’t even try. 

In territorial sovereignty societies, the bounty does not go to the people.  The land is in a country and has an owner.  The country makes primary rules about the wealth (obviously, the leaders of the country will get something) and the owners make the secondary rules.  There is no wealth that flows to ‘the human race’ or even ‘the people.’  No wealth means no resources to protect their interests.  They are at the mercy of the people who do have resources.

Generally, the people who do have resources are either wealthy people, owners, or people who have gained powerful positions in government.  The people at the very top are generally in all three categories at the same time: they are wealthy, they own large amounts of cash-flow generating land (so they get enormous incomes) and they have political power.  These people make the rules. They decide what they want.  If they want to make changes in society that harm the human race as a whole, or ‘their own people,’ they can do this. 

Natural law societies have a very simple incentive profile.  So far, we have looked at half of it.  We have seen that the internal reward systems of natural law societies naturally encourage environment, personal, and social responsibility.  People don’t just get good feelings inside their hearts of they act responsibly, they get cold hard cash (in societies that use money for transactions).  The amount of money they get depends on how good they are at keeping the environment healthy, maintaining good relationships with as many people as possible, and making sure that the basic functions of society work smoothly and benefit everyone.

Unfortunately, natural law societies also have some extremely undesirable and even dangerous incentives. These societies are so dangerous that they basically disqualify natural law societies as options for us now:  we can’t hope to save ourselves by trying to convert to natural law societies.

However, that doesn’t mean that we can’t profit by studying them.  they do have very desirable incentives.  Territorial sovereignty societies also have desirable incentives.  It turns out that these two incentive structures are basically complimentary.  Territorial sovereignty societies have incentives that natural law societies don’t have but need, and vice versa.  If we understand why this happens, we can design societies that are basically hybrids, giving us the best of both starting societies without the disadvantages of either. 

Now let’s consider where natural law societies fail us and the reason that they are not able to help save us from our current dilemma.

Constructive Incentives

There are a lot of ways to get rich in territorial sovereignty societies.

The easiest way is to be born with rich parents.  Unfortunately for me, I didn’t know this in time and, by the time I figured it out, it was too late as I was already born.  But there are other options. 

You can also invent something, discovery something, or find a new way to do things that make life better for others. You can also improve some part of the world.  You can buy something, a run down house for example or a farm that needs something it doesn’t have, fix it up, and sell it.  You can make fantastic amounts on the increases in prices.  The difference between the price you sell the property for and the price you buy is called the ‘capital gain.’  You can make fantastic capital gains for doing things that really aren’t very hard.  Mainly because people can make these capital gains, territorial sovereignty societies have very strong incentives for people to gain control of property somehow (usually by buying it), making improvements, and then selling.

In want to give a quick example:

If you look on Loopnet.com or some other website where farms are bought and sold, you will find thousands of ‘properties’ for sale all around the world.  Nearly all of the ads will mention the ‘free cash flow’ of the property very prominently; they know that people who are buying properties are far more likely to buy a property that generates free cash and will pay significantly more money for a property that generates a higher free cash flow than a low one.

As I write this in 2022, farms are selling for about 20 times the free cash flow.  This means that a farm like the Pastland Farm, with a free cash flow of $2.4 million, will be offered for about $50 million, with the expectation that buyers will make offers slightly lower than the asking price and the farm will eventually sell for about $48 million.   A farm with a free cash flow that is 20% higher, or $2.88 million, will be offered for about  $59.6 million with the expectation it will sell for about $57.6 million. 

Consider this:  Say you could find a farm like the Pastland Farm for sale on Loopnet.com.  (Don’t worry about not having the money; if you have good credit you can borrow.) Say there is a way that you can make changes to drive up the free cash flow by 20%.  (In fact, this would be quite easy to do; see textbox below.) Then, you sell for the higher price. You buy for $48 million and sell for $57.6 million, putting $9.6 million in your pocket, minus whatever it takes to make the change.  

Say you can get the improvements made for $1 million.  (In other words you can hire people to do everything required to make this work for $1 million.  You can get the real estate people working for you, hire people to draw up the plans, get the permits, and actually do the work, then put the improved property on the market again and take care of the paperwork. After all this is done, you will get a check for $9.6 million.) 

You make a gain of $9.6 million and pay a cost of $1 million, leaving you with $8.6 million left over. 

You can spend this or invest it.

If you invest it at 5%, you will be able to sit back and collect $430,000 in returns, without ever doing anything again for the rest of your life.  

Assuming you can borrow the money to make this work, you will basically have to make a few phone calls and tell people what to do.  Then, a few months later, you will be set for life, making more than 10 times the income of an average worker who will have to work 40 hours a week for the rest of his career, without doing a single thing, ever. 

 

A sample improvement:

So far, in Pastland, the Pastland Farm is in its natural state:  we have not done anything to it.  Before humans arrived, other animals collected the rice that grew and reseeded the land.  Now humans do this.  Other than that, nothing has changed. 

 

Nature made this good rice land.

But it did not make it perfect.

 

For one thing, it is not perfectly 100% laser leveled. 

There are high spots including some pieces of ground that stick completely out of the water.  Rice barely grows there.  There are also low spots where the water is too deep for rice.  Rice doesn’t grow there at all.  If you could level the land, moving the dirt from the high spots to the low spots (with a machine that runs off of a laser, so it is level to within a few millimeters) it would produce more.  It is quite common for production to go up by 20% when natural land is leveled. 

In order to understand improvement incentives in different societies, we need what we call a ‘sample improvement.’  This is an improvement that can be made in any society.  In some societies, people will be able to make themselves fantastically wealthy by finding ways to gain control of the property (buying the rights that are for sale), improving, and then disposing of the property (selling the rights again). 

 

In other societies, this improvement will actually cost more to make than it will bring in benefits to the people who make it.  If people lose money by making improvements, they have incentives to actually resist improvements and prevent them from being made. We can compare incentives this book calls ‘constructive incentives’ by comparing the amounts people make improving. We can look at this ‘sample improvement’ first to learn about the basic principles involved.  Then, once we understand these principles, we can look at other things we might improve (there are a lot of ways to improve the amount of wealth the world provides) to see if the same principles apply.  If they do, we will understand the forces that can push for growth and progress in some societies which do not operate in other societies and which actually work to impede growth in some societies. 

 

Sample improvement:

Level land of Pastland Farm.  Production and costs both go up by 20% so free cash flow (and bounty) go up by 20%.  A total of $1 million is required to hire people to do everything required for this improvement.

 

If I could find a deal like this, I would jump on it. 

In fact, people are scouring all sales websites constantly to look for deals like this. 

This is why all rice farms have already been leveled. 

There are always people looking for farms that can easily be improved. 

If they find them, they buy them, improve them, and resell them.  I have been in many countries, from the poorest to the richest, and seen many rice farms.  Every one of them has already been leveled.   If it is on flat land, when it is flooded for seeding there is a mirror-smooth finish on the water, even though it is only a few inches deep.  The water looks the same color because the depth is exactly the same everywhere.  If is on a hill, it is terraced, with each terrace looking the same.  People even grow rice on very steep mountains.  When they do, the terraces look like staircases, one flat step after the next.  It doesn’t matter what religion people are.  Their political party or affiliation doesn’t matter.  Their language doesn’t matter.  Even in areas without roads, electricity, or schools, the land is level. This is so common, in sovereignty based societies, that many people might think that this is just the way human beings treat rice land.  There is something about ‘human nature’ that makes us want to see the flatness and levelness.

But this isn’t true:

The book ‘The Wild Rice Gatherers Of The Upper Lakes; A Study In American Primitive Economics’ discusses the practices of the people who lived on some of what is now the most productive rice land in the world, before their land was conquered and taken over by people from territorial sovereignty societies.  It describes the practices of these people in detail.  It has pictures.  (You can find this book on the PossibleSocieties.com website.)  The author, Ernest Jenks, has interviews with the native people who still lived off of these lands in the late 1800s, before the last of the people born and raised in natural law societies who refused to renounce their way of life were forcibly removed from these highly productive lands and put on ‘reservations.’ 

If you look at the pictures, you can see that the land was far from level.

In fact, the land looks basically unchanged from the way nature made it.

In 1803-1805, Lewis and Clark made a voyage from the headwaters of the Mississippi river in what is now the state of Minnesota to the mouth of the Columbia river in what is now the state of Washington.  They traveled slowly.  Merewether Lewis, in particular, liked to walk and would walk through the meadows alongside the rivers while the crews pulled the boats along.  He remarked often of the incredible variety of nature and how rich and healthy the lands were.  He also commented on how strange it was that this rich land was not cultivated.

When the crew stopped for the night or rested, the native people would invite them to their villages and feed them. The staple food in the Pacific Northwest was bread which was made of the roots of the camas plant. 

 

Camas bread has an unusual starch that standard molds and bacteria can’t use for food, so it can keep far longer than breads made of grains like wheat or rye.  With proper storage, it can last several years.  It was extremely common in the Pacific Northwest and, because it can keep so long, was a very valuable trade good.  Camas bread is baked in ovens called ‘camas ovens,’ generally made of pits that were dug and lined with rocks, then covered to hold in the heat. The ovens are found everywhere in the Pacific Northwest and have been dated to more than 5,000 BC. 

 

When the natives wanted camas to make bread, they natural meadows; they dug it up, dried it, ground it, and baked the bread.  The observers thought that the natives were simply hunter gatherers:  nature made the camas grow and they simply gathered it.

We now know that camas has to be cultivated:  it is never safe to eat wild camas because one out every 100 plants or so develops into something called ‘death camas.’  It is deadly poisonous and if you eat it you die. The only way known to identify death camas is by the flowers.  You need to go to the field, find the dangerous plants, and kill them at the right time of the year.  Otherwise you won’t know which are ‘death camas’ and which are safe:  grind them together and eat the bread and everyone dies.

The natives did practice agriculture. Many of their crops had to be cultivated.  But they didn’t treat their agricultural land the way people from the conquering societies did.  They didn’t alter it and modify it, plow it and shape it to try to drive up the value of the land as did people in territorial sovereignty societies, because they didn’t buy and sell land.  They grew crops but grew them so much differently than the invaders that the invaders didn’t even realize they were looking at ‘intentionally cultivated farms’ when they saw them. 

A Comparison

In territorial sovereignty societies, everything is ownable. 

The people who run the governments of the individual territorial units have sovereignty.  This means they can create any laws they want.  (Subject, of course, to any limitations the ‘founders’ of the country created when they made the country.)   If they want people to be able to own ideas, they can make ideas ownable, by making patents, copyrights, and trade secrets ownable. If they want people to build factories, they make collective financial systems like ‘anonymous, zero liability, joint stock companies’ ownable. 

 

Anonymous, zero liability joint stock corporations:

The book Forensic History explains the way key structures of the world around use came to exist and how they evolved into their present form over time. The entities called ‘corporations’ play a key role in the societies that exist now and many corporations actually have far more power, wealth, and control over the realities of our world, than some countries.  (For example, the decisions of the people who run General Electric, Google, Amazon, and Facebook have greater impact on world events than the decisions of the governments of the country of Seychelles, or Comoros, or Swaziland.)  If we want to understand how and why world works, we can’t understand this if we only understand countries and don’t understand corporations.

 

Territorial sovereignty societies have powerful forces pushing toward the activity called ‘war’ and this activity can come at any time.  The people who run the individual territorial units (countries) need to make sure their country can compete in war or it will be wiped out, with its territory becoming a part of the conquering country.  The people who ran these countries realized they could great advantages if they could create systems where large numbers of people could work together to create giant factories, mines, and other businesses. They found that people weren’t anxious to get involved in these projects if they thought  they could be held personally responsible for things that went wrong in their business.  (If people who invested in explosive factories could lose their homes and personal possessions because an accident killed some people, they wouldn’t want to invest.  Weapons are, by their very nature, dangerous things that can kill people.  Weapons factories wouldn’t exist if people who invested in them could be held personally responsible.)  They dealt with this by creating something called ‘limited liability corporations,’ where the ‘liability of owners’ was ‘limited’ to the amount of money they invested.  In other words, if you invest $100 in a weapons factory and it blows up killing thousands, the most you can lose is the $100.  You have zero personal liability for anything that happens.  The factory could destroy an entire state (which is possible for factories that produce nuclear bombs), cause trillions in damage and kill millions of people and you wouldn’t have to worry about losing a single cent of your own money. These kinds of corporations have existed for thousands of years.  The Roman war machine was supplied by corporations, with materials taken from corporate mines; the soldiers went to war on roads that corporations built out of cement made by corporate cement plants.  The details were worked out in giant buildings—many of which still exist after thousands of years—that were made by corporations. 

 

By law, the owners were safe from anything the corporations did.  However, by the 1600s, corporations had gained so much power and control that many of them were substantially larger than the countries that sponsored them, and the laws of this country couldn’t protect the owners entirely.  The giant VOC (the Dutch East India Company) was substantially larger than the county that sponsored the corporation.  If people could find out who owned the company, they could use various tricks in their home countries to hold the owners accountable for the actions of their companies. 

The VOC was the first company to come up with the solution that is now a practice thorough the world:   Create an ownership system that allows the owners to be anonymous.  If no one can find out who the owners are, no one can hold the owners accountable. The Dutch government created public markets for shares in the corporations and allowed buyers in these markets to register their shares in the name of a broker.  (If you own stock in a brokerage account, you can ask them to register the stock in a ‘street name’ so that your name won’t be listed in any corporate records.  If your stock is registered in your own name, you can call any brokerage pretty much anywhere in the world and set up an account.  You can then sell your registered sharers in a market while buying the same shares back for the benefit of the brokerage.  Tell them to ‘register in a street name’ and your name won’t be on anything.  In the event you are worried about the brokerage being pressured to give up your name, you can form a ‘shell’ corporation to own the brokerage account and hold the shares of the ‘shell’ in a ‘street name’ in another brokerage account in another country.  The laws of each country protect you and anyone trying to find out who you are must get through every layer to find out who you are.  In practice, this is so difficult it is impossible and, if you go through at least two layers of shells, you are basically totally safe.)

 

The people who run the entities called ‘governments’ want their county to be able to compete in war.  They have sovereignty (they can do anything they want that isn’t prohibited by the restrictions set up by the founders). They can make anything they want ownable.  After Holland set up this system, the lawmakers in England realized its advantages and copied it.  Other countries couldn’t hope to defend themselves against England and Holland unless they copied the systems themselves.  In our 21st century world, all countries have laws that protect the people who benefit from the existence of dangerous business enterprises from liability in various ways, with the two listed above being the most common.

The entities called ‘governments of countries’ can pass laws that make it legal to own pretty much anything and then protect the rights of the owners.  The owners can then by and sell their rights in ways that allow them to make fantastic sums of money by ownership of things we may not even consider to be important, like even the simplest ideas.

Here is an example:  In 2009, Jack Dorsey came up with the idea of a media company that had very, very short ‘stories.’  This company wouldn’t allow any story to be more than 140 characters long. He knew that people had very short attention spans.  They thought they would be more likely to spend time on a site that had lots of stories they could read in a few seconds, than on traditional media sites where it took several minutes to read a single story.  Dorsey and some of his friends bought servers and set up a system where people could post these stories, which they called ‘tweets.’  They didn’t want to have to worry about possible personal liability for damage that might be caused when people posted things that led to violence, so they created a corporation for this.  (See text box above for more about liability and corporations.)   They called it ‘twitter’ and called the extremely short stories ‘tweets.’

They had no idea how they would make money from it and didn’t even really try.  They just thought it would be popular and figured that, if a lot of people came to their site, someone else would figure out a way to make money out of it.  The people who figured this out would buy their process by buying the corporation that they had created, ‘Twitter Incorporated.’  In 2013, a lot of people had ideas for this and began to make offers for the company. They people who created it began to sell at a price that represented a total value for the corporation of $1.8 billion.  Dorsey became one of the richest people on earth overnight.  He sold his shares and used part of the money to create other corporations that incorporated other new ideas.  Now his is worth $4.6 billion.  (Actually, we can’t say the exact amount because his wealth is in ownership shares in companies and their value changes every second of every day the market is open. Between the time you start this sentence and the time you finish it, he may be $100 million richer.) 

This kind of thing happens in territorial sovereignty societies.  The people who run the countries can make anything they want ownable, including ideas. (They have sovereignty which means they can do anything the laws created by the founders and people who came before them don’t prohibit.) These societies start with the idea that parts of planets are ownable.  They extend the ideas related to ‘ownership of parts of planets’ to other things they want to be ownable. 

This chapter is not about territorial sovereignty societies, it is about natural law societies.  I am only discussing territorial sovereignty societies here so you can see that the realities of natural law societies and territorial sovereignty societies are totally different and the way people can get rich in these societies are totally different.  (The next chapter discusses the practical realities of territorial sovereignty societies and shows how they work.) 

A lot of the ‘ways people can get rich’ in territorial sovereignty societies seem mysterious.  Where, exactly, does the $4.6 billion that Jack Dorsey has come from?  What process caused this money to flow to him, who gave it up, and why did they give it up?  The processes that cause people to get money in territorial sovereignty societies are far more complicated than the processes that cause people to get money in natural law societies. It is pretty easy to understand how people get money in natural law societies and all the flows of money make a lot of sense.  Since we know where the money comes from and how it gets to the people who end up with it, we can easily understand the incentives.

In natural law societies it is easy to see why people get money and where it comes from.  The system in Pastland is particularly simple (I created it to be easy to understand).  Each year, all rice the land produced is sold (exchanged for money).  We put all the money on a table.  We then decide what to do with it.  Some of it goes to people who work and do things that benefit us. We know we are better off letting them have this money and give it to them.  But the world is bountiful so, after we have paid them, the great majority of the money is left over.  This is the ‘free cash flow’ of the land:  the money that flows from the land each year.  We divide this evenly.  Everyone gets whatever money they have earned plus an equal share of the unearned wealth. 

But in territorial sovereignty societies, people can make fantastic amounts of money without doing anything. Dorsey didn’t make his $4.6 billon as salary, as pay for anything he did, or as profits.  He got this money by ‘owning’ things.  The amounts of money that people can make by ‘owning things’ is so vast, in these societies, that it dwarfs the amounts of money people can make working, providing services, or even by operating profitable businesses.  (Twitter had not generated a single dime of revenue when Dorsey became a billionaire.) 

Now let’s expand this to a larger scale:  In November of 2021, the market value of all publicly traded stocks sold on organized stock market exchanges was $109 trillion.  This was an increase of 19.7% over the previous year, so the people who owned these stocks made roughly $21.473 trillion that year.  The ‘global GDP’ or the ‘total money value of every good created and every service provided everywhere on earth’ was $93.86 trillion that year.  The people who owned publicly traded stocks made enough money to buy more than 20% of this. 

And this is just one asset class.  In other words, it is just one of the ‘things that people can make money owning in territorial sovereignty societies that can’t be owned at all in natural law societies.’  I chose it for this example because data is easy to find so there can’t be any controversy over them.  How much money do ‘owners of the many items that can be owned in territorial sovereignty societies that can’t be owned in natural law societies’ get, in total, each year?  How much of the ‘things of value created and services provided on the earth’ are purchased with this money?  How does this compare to the amount of wealth that people can get by working at a job or by making actual profits by operating a business that creates value?

Why do people get money in territorial sovereignty societies?  What are the structures that make this happen?  What are the side effects of the operations of these structures? What incentives does this distribution of wealth create?

To answer these questions, we need to examine territorial sovereignty societies and that is not the purpose of this chapter.  But there is one thing we can say for sure, without knowing the answers to these questions:  territorial sovereignty societies allow people to get very rich if they do things that lead to progress, advances in technology, and growth in the ability of the land to create value. We may argue about whether Jack Dorsey really made the world better in any substantial way by creating Twitter. Perhaps the people who use his product only think their lives are better, because they have snippets of stories that they can use as talking points to make people think they understand things that they don’t really understand.  But this society offers such fantastic rewards to people who do things that may possibly improve life that even creating an illusion that he made life better (by making sure they never saw ‘stories’ that were longer than 140 characters) made him a multi-billionaire. 

We can’t know exactly why these flows of value encourage people to try new things without understanding the details, but we can see there is a connection:  people will think and plan.  They will get up before dawn, chugging coffee to pull them to alertness, so they can get to work solving problems with their idea.  They will make their children do without things they want so they can hire people to help them or buy equipment they need to help with their work.  They will spend all day, every day, welded to their workspace, keeping jars around so they don’t have to leave even long enough to go to the bathroom.  They will lose track of time as the hours and days drift by, only stopping when their bodies can no longer function due to the lack of sleep.  They will take incredible risks and chances, putting everything they have earned their entire lives on the line, just on the hope that they can be the next Jack Dorsey. 

Territorial sovereignty societies clearly have some kind of incentive system that does NOT exist in natural law societies that pushes people in them to do these things.  Because of ‘whatever these incentives are’ we have media and advertising venues that would not otherwise exist.  We also have electricity (Edison was clearly driven by his work), phones, televisions, jets, computers, solar panels, and audio-video cameras that can capture and record everything that happens around us with better resolution than our eyes and ears can detect. 

Territorial sovereignty societies are dynamic societies:  they are always changing.   They change so fast that it is scary.  Often, people in these societies make more progress in a single year than the entire human race made in the entire 344,000 years that we were on this world before the first territorial sovereignty societies came to exist about 6,000 years ago. 

Natural law societies are not dynamic societies.  They can remain unchanged for incredibly long periods of time. Humans have had fire, clothing, and the ability to make homes for hundreds of thousands of years.  (Forensic History provides the evidence for this.)  You might imagine how these people lived.  If you then pick up the Journals of Lewis and Clark from their voyages in 1803-1805, you will find descriptions of the way the people who still had natural law societies in North America lived.  They lived with at three large communities of these people for many months (the Hidatsu of Minnesota, the Nez Pierce of Idaho, and the numerous tribes that lived together along the coasts of what is now Oregon and Washington in the winter of 1805).  They describe the way these people lived in great detail. When I read these descriptions, I can imagine that the same people lived the exact same way a century earlier; in fact, they may have lived the same way a thousand years earlier, or even ten thousand years earlier.  Their way of life may well be no different than it was when the first humans came to this area. 

Our group in Pastland has a natural law society.  The incentive systems of these societies ‘condition’ us and lead to certain realities we would expect.  We are all harmed if the land around us is harmed so we have incentives to make sure no harm comes to it.  We are all ‘paid’ for personal, social, and environmental responsibility:  we get a share of the bounty of the world around us if the people who decide who gets this money/wealth agree to let us have it. We have incentives to make sure the people around us see us as responsible people.  But the forces that push for progress, growth, technological advances, investment, discovery, and invention in territorial sovereignty societies do not exist in our natural law society.

This does not mean that there will never be progress and no one will ever invent anything. Incentives are not behaviors, they are behavioral motivations.  People have ideas in any society.  They may not be able to make any money off of them, but they often try to make things work even if there is no money in it.  Some of these ideas work out.  But even if they do, natural law societies don’t allow people to take ownership of these ideas and buy and sell rights to them in ways that will allow them to create large-scale systems that will allow the ideas to advance.  The ideas may be passed down from generation to generation for a few generations through some oral descriptions, but mostly as curiosities. But there is no pressure to figure out how to alter these new things in ways that will turn them into specific products that are in demand.  They discoveries eventually are lost and become a part of history.

For example, consider the metal bronze, made by mixing copper and tin.  It is far stronger than either individual metal and extremely useful, particularly as weapons in warfare.  There is evidence that people made bronze items, in small quantities, in natural law societies, off and on, for thousands of years.  But the process didn’t become a regular part of human societies in general until about 2000 BC, well into the age of territorial sovereignty societies. when weapons makers found about its advantages.  (Many people like to decorate themselves with jewelry.  This is true in the societies we inherited and was true in natural law societies.  People making jewelry generally have to heat metals and mix them, to create different colors for the finished products.) 

Things are discovered.  But no one puts together formal systems to turn these discoveries into useful items and build them in large numbers. Eventually, the discoveries are lost. This can explain why the natives of America were able to live in very primitive conditions, even though they had been around for many thousands of years and showed the same level of curiosity and intelligence as people in the world today:  these societies didn’t have any forces that even allowed them to maintain their current level of technology, let alone improve it.   

Reversion to Primitiveness in Pastland

Our group in Pastland brought back a lot of wonderful things from the future.  We have the ship itself, made mostly of steel (an item that doesn’t normally exist in nature and has to be manufactured by humans).  We have computers, the generators and solar panels we use to generate our electricity, refrigerators to keep our food from spoiling, machines to help us sow the seeds and harvest the things the land gives us, radios, televisions, telephones, and the internet. 

We have these things now, but they aren’t going to last forever.  When they break, we won’t have parts to fix them.

The ship is made almost entirely of steel.  If steel gets exposed to oxygen from the air, it starts rusting immediately.  Steel parts have to be protected by paint or they will rust to nothing.  We didn’t bring paint with us from the future.  A lot of paint was scraped from the ship in the events related to the time warp and many parts of the ship are already rusting.  Within a few decades, structures that were once thick enough to drive a tank across will be thin enough to poke a hand through.  Within a few generations, the floors and walls of the ship will be paper-thin and the ship will be so dangerous that we won’t be able to live there anymore.

We will have to move out onto the land.

If we still have an absolute prohibition on ownability and prohibit any alterations to the land, we will have to live in temporary structures like the teepees that the American natives in this area used before the first European people arrived.

When we arrived in the past, we had electricity produced by generators and solar panels.  We had a great many products that used electricity to operate. These items have moving parts.  Generators have rotors that turn on bearings, and bearings eventually wear out.  Eventually our generators will break, and we won’t have the parts to fix them.

When the last of our generating devices fail, all our electrical devices will become useless.  All the data that was on hard drives will be lost forever.  If we have no paper factories, we won’t be able to write any of this information down and will have to pass it down to future generations verbally.  It won’t take long before the great bulk of the information about how to make things that we brought back from the future will be lost.

We will have babies: we don’t need any technology or factories for this; no investments are required.  Have sex and babies will come.  We have plentiful food; even without machines to collect the food, we will all have plenty to eat.  Babies will have good nutrition and grow up healthy. 

Before modern birth control methods came into existence, the average woman gave birth about 8 times in her life. If half of the babies survived to breeding age themselves, the population would double in a single generation.  (Four offspring would be alive and ready to reproduce from the original couple.) 

If the population doubles every generation, it will increase by a factor of 32 every century and by a factor of more than 1000 every 200 years.  We don’t need technology for population to grow.  All we need is food and we have plenty of that. 

The human population of the earth will grow.  We will spread out across the land.  Children will hear the stories of all of the wonderful things that people used to have, like giant ships that sailed the oceans, computers that stored vast amounts of data, and refrigerating devices that provided wonderful treats like ice cream on the hottest days.  In time, children will start to think of these stories as nonsense; stories told by adults for some unknown reason that really have no relationship to anything real or important in their lives.

They will stop believing these things.

Parents will not waste time telling their children stories that they don’t believe themselves.  All of the information we brought back from us from the 21st century will be forgotten.

Why Does this Matter?

If we keep the natural law society, we will eventually wind up living much as the American native people lived, as described by Lewis and Clark in their journals. 

Some may say this isn’t a bad thing at all.

These people lived in harmony with the land.

They did have conflicts, but they didn’t form giant organizations to take wealth from the people as taxes and pay massive corporations to make weapons.  Their conflicts were ‘like the games of children’ compared to the conflicts that took place in territorial sovereignty societies.  No one would have to worry about being wiped out in a nuclear war or destroyed by global warming. 

In fact, when both cultures existed at the same time, a great many people basically ‘ran away’ from territorial sovereignty societies to live with the people of natural law societies. Records from the first few centuries of the settlement of North America discuss the problems tracking down both slaves and indentured servants (white slaves) who ran away from their masters. If the slaves/servants ran away to join the ‘Indians,’ they generally would never be recaptured.  Many people left the societies of the conquerors to live with the natives for the simpler lives.  Some of them eventually returned to society and wrote books about their experiences.  (Alexander Henry wrote a very good book about the 7 years he lived this way.)  The lifestyle of these people still holds some appeal today and many people spend small fortunes to have an opportunity to live ‘the way the Indians lived’ for a few weeks a year during their vacations. 

Why not keep the natural law society in Pastland indefinitely? 

In fact, this is not a solution to the problem we face.  Although natural law societies can last longer than territorial sovereignty societies, they have a very serious problem that will eventually cause them to go away too.   At times, the people of these societies will live through poverty that is almost unimaginable to people who live in territorial sovereignty societies.  They will watch people starve to death daily.  They will not be able to sleep for the crying of children who have not been fed.  They will have to resort to horrible practices that include infanticide, gericide, and even ritual human sacrifices to cull their population to match the food supply. 

They will look for anything that can help.

They will realize that letting people own can help.  If people can own parts of planets, they have incentives to do things that improve it and drive up the amount it produces.  There will be real, practical, pressure to change the foundational principles of their societies. 

This pressure was a part of human existence for hundreds of thousands of years.  But there was incredible resistance to it.  Natural law societies have very desirable features.  They seem fair and reasonable:  people get paid for doing things that improve social, environment, and personal realities.  They don’t get paid for doing things that harm others and the world.  To people raised in natural law societies, the idea of accepting the ownership of parts of planets seems crazy.

The book Forensic History goes over the records of the conquest and discusses the many attempts to get the native people abandon their cultures and assimilate themselves into the conquering culture.  These attempts began very early:  the Spanish government didn’t want to have to kill of people to gain control of the land.  The proclamation called the ‘requiremento,’ distributed by crier in the native language to all the people of Haiti, told them that the king welcomed them as subjects if they only acted like other subjects of the crown.  They had to follow the laws, pay rent for their homes to the people the king had given the land, pay for the food they took from the land, which was now privately owned, and pay their taxes just like the whites.  If they did this, they would be welcomed and given all the rights the generous king gave all his subjects.  If not, the king would treat them with great brutality, capturing those he could capture to work to death in the mines and killing all others.  In the end, the people native people of Haiti chose not to comply.  They were wiped out.

 

Many other attempts were made to assimilate the native people.  The conquerors set up schools to teach them about how the creator had set up countries and allocated land to the countries in the early days of human existence. (You can find these discussions in Chapter 10 of the First Book of Moses, called ‘Genesis’ in the Christian version.)   They told them about the principle of ‘manifest destiny,’ which holds that the creator wanted each part of the world to be owned by certain countries and he made the destiny of each part ‘manifest’ by giving the country he wanted to have it the ability to take it. But people raised in natural law societies had learned that humans, like all other animals, depend n nature and the natural world.  The entities called ‘countries’ were not stronger than nature and could not own it and force it to do their bidding.  They didn’t accept.

The conquerors then set up boarding schools where the children from native communities would be housed away from their families and culture.  They thought that if the children weren’t contaminated by their families and culture, they would accept the conquering culture and assimilate themselves into it.  This didn’t work either.  Even the hardest-hearted whites gave in around Christmas and let the children go home for the holidays.  It only took a few days and the children were just as intractable as if they had remained on the reservation. 

 

In the 1860s, the government decided the only way to assimilate any of the people was to take children away from their parents and the reservations entirely.  They generally took them at birth, so there would be no risk of mental contamination and gave them to whites to raise as their own.  I was raised partly with my uncle and aunt who had a ranch outside of Ashland Montana.  My aunt had been raised near a uranium mine and been exposed to radioactive tailings, so they couldn’t have children of their own.  The United States government had declared the Rosebud Indian Reservation as ‘an unsuitable place to raise children.’  The law allowed them to take children way from their mothers at any stage to take them out of this bad environment and put them up for adoption. My uncle and aunt got two children through this program.  (It was shut down in 1973, as a result of agreements made during the Indian insurrection on the nearby Ridge reservation.  The insurrectionists had gained global media attention—everywhere except  in the United States, where the press was barred from covering it—and universal condemnation for its treatment of the Indians; this particular practice was classified as ‘genocide’ by the United Nations.  In order to end the insurrection, the United States government agreed to end the practice and passed the ‘Indian Adoption Act’ in 1974 to comply with this promise.

 

All attempts to assimilate these people failed. The only real solution was to reduce their numbers so much and subject them to such intense poverty that they were basically wards of the state.  This remains the policy (unofficially, of course) today.

 

The people may resist the temptation to change the foundation of their society for incredibly long periods of time. But eventually, one group somewhere will not be able to resist. 

Perhaps, if they had a science of society that would allow them to understand other systems, they may convert to a system that has the same advantages of the natural law society and has a limited kind of ownability that grants ownership of the rights to profit by improving land (perhaps allowing them to own the right to keep all of the increased value for a certain period of time, like the rest of their lives).  But if they don’t have a science of societies, they will not know these kinds of systems are even possible.  To them, the choice will be:  no rights to the world ownable or sovereign rights (all rights) ownable. In other words, if they don’t know about other options, all they do is have either natural law societies or territorial sovereignty societies.

A Fatal Flaw

The chart below shows what happens to the population of a group that starts at 1,000 and grows at an average rate of 3% per year.  This represents three children per couple that survive to breeding age.  Note that after 40 generations, or 1,000 years, the population that starts at 1,000 will be above 1 billion.   This is about the 2022 population of the entire American landmass.  

Long before a thousand years have passed, there won’t be enough food for the people.  But, without birth control, the babies will keep coming. Eventually, the people in the natural law societies will have to take desperate measures to deal with the problem. Most of these measures are too horrible for us to even think about.  (Infanticide, gericide, and human sacrifices—often where people volunteered   to die for the good of the community—were parts of many American societies when the conquers first arrived.) 

 

Generations

Years

population

0

0

 1,000

2

50

 2,000

4

100

 4,000

6

150

 8,000

8

200

 16,000

10

250

 32,000

12

300

 64,000

14

350

 128,000

16

400

 256,000

18

450

 512,000

20

500

 1,024,000

22

550

 2,048,000

24

600

 4,096,000

26

650

 8,192,000

28

700

 16,384,000

30

750

 32,768,000

32

800

 65,536,000

34

850

 131,072,000

36

900

 262,144,000

38

950

 524,288,000

40

1000

 1,048,576,000

42

1050

 2,097,152,000

44

1100

 4,194,304,000

46

1150

 8,388,608,000

 

In the end, the lack of constructive incentives will be a fatal flaw for natural law societies and cause them to disappear. 

Why? 

Eventually, some group somewhere will come accept the idea that a certain group of people is the natural owner of a certain part of the planet with total sovereignty over it.  It is their sovereign territory. 

Once a group has this other type of society, that group’s production will grow, and its technology will advance. The people in this group will be raised to believe that the land belongs to the country that claims it.  People from the first country will head out to areas where there are no countries and form their own countries.  Countries will have conflicts with other existing countries over which country certain parts of the world belong to.  The people who run the countries will need to defend the land they claim is theirs.  If two countries claim the same land, conflict is inevitable.  If one side uses force and the other doesn’t, the side that uses force will win.  Everyone will see this.  Each country will have to have its own military or it won’t be able to protect the land it claims.

The countries will generally find it is easier to take land controlled by the people who still have the old system than to take land controlled by an existing country.  They will move out and expand.  Countries that can expand faster and gain more land will be able to build bigger armies, allowing them to dominate other existing countries.  The people who run countries will organize for conquest.  They will be able to take land very rapidly.

The expanding territorial sovereignty societies will face competition, but very little of this will come from the people who have natural law societies.  People from other countries will fight them to gain control of the best land.  These fights will be brutal and vicious, with enormous numbers of people in the competing countries dying to gain priority for their particular ‘country.’ 

As a strategic measure, the countries will have to conquer even land that doesn’t have any real use by the conquerors.  (It can’t be profitably farmed and doesn’t contain minerals or other resources.)  They will have to take all the land.  If they leave any land to be not a part of a country, competitors will take it and use it as a base to launch attacks on the more desirable land.  The expanding countries will eventually take everything. 

Nothing will be left unowned and unownable. 

Natural law societies may exist for a very long time.  But they will eventually disappear.

This is an important observation for our group in Pastland.  If we can accept that the natural law societies are temporary, and will eventually disappear anyway, we might as well use our technology, our skills, talents, and the other advantages that we have to figure out something better and put it into place while this is easy for us to do. 

What else is possible?

To understand this, we really need to understand the features of societies that accept ownability.  Let’s take a mental trip—a ‘thought experiment’—and see if we can figure out aspects of societies that accept ownability that we can incorporate into the simple natural law societies we started with to create a sound system that can meet the needs of the human race indefinitely into the future. 

 

 

7 Territorial Sovereignty Societies

Written by Annie Nymous on . Posted in 1: Possible Societies, 2: Part Two: Natural Law Societies, Books

Things could have happened differently in Pastland.

When we first arrived, a lot of people argued about which country the land was around us belonged to.  In the example above, put off the fighting by having a moratorium on letting any person or country own any part of the planet, essentially creating a territorial sovereignty society.

We could have done something differently: 

Many people in our world today think that ownership of land is basically a good thing, but the problem is unequal distribution of the land.  If everyone had the same amount of land, everyone would be equal.  We could then live in harmony, even though we had ownership. 

Someone suggests that, to stop the fighting, we must make everyone equal.  We divide the productive land into 1000 equal parcels, one for each of us, and then distribute them by lot.  There are 1,500 acres, so everyone will get 1.5 acres. 

We really aren’t in a position to give the proposal a great deal of thought.  People are fighting NOW.  They are tearing apart the ship to make weapons.  We need to put an end to this so that we can get along.  Finally, we decide to accept this idea and divide the land.  We have people go out with whatever equipment we have (tape measures, levels, sticks, string) to divide the land.  We draw up a map and number the parcels one through one thousand.  We put slips of paper with the numbers into a hat and everyone draws a slip. 

You draw a number, let’s say it is 333.  Parcel 333 belongs to you. You have to look on the map to find it. then you have to trudge through the swamp to find the stakes that mark the corners. 

You are now a person of property.

Some part of the world belongs to you.

Practical Matters

If you want to get a mental picture of your farm, imagine a piece of swamp where wild rice grows.  It has been divided into 1000 parcels with stakes and string.  One of the parcels is parcel number 333:  this is your farm.  It is a square with sides 250 feet by 250 feet.  Your farm is square.  You have four neighbors, one on each side.  The property likes are marked with string stretched between stakes that are pounded into the soft mud. 

Divisiveness

Your land is marked by stakes that are pushed into soft mud.  Strings stretch tight to other stakes and these strings mark your property lines.  If you go to a stake, you can push it a little and it will move. 

If you can move your lot lines out by 1 inch, your parcel of land will be 21 square feet bigger.  This may not sound like much and it isn’t.  But this extra 21 square feet of land will produce about 2 pounds.  If it is in your land, it is your 2 pounds of rice.  If it is in the neighbors land, it is their rice. 

Each of the farms is quite tiny.  Many of us are not going to be good farmers and aren’t going to make our own farms produce enough to keep ourselves alive.   Others are barely going to make it.  A few square feet of additional land can make the difference between living and dying to these people. 

We could all live on the ship if we wanted to.  But if you are on the ship, you aren’t going to be able to keep an eye on your property.  Your neighbors may normally be honest.  But if you aren’t watching, there is a chance one of them may move her stake out to take away some of your land.  You won’t be able to take a chance on this.  Most of us are going to take whatever we can from the ship and set up camp on our land.

As long as the property lines are string with sticks, a lot of people are going to be afraid.  They need some sort of durable barrier, something that is hard to move.  A pile of rocks for a corner is harder to move than a stick, but if you leave for a few hours, it can be moved a few inches.  The best thing to do is to build a wall.  The higher and stronger the wall, the safer you are going to be.

If you look at any ariel photo anyplace that has territorial sovereignty societies, you will see the walls separating people from each other.  They are obvious.  Territorial sovereignty societies work in many ways that divide people into different groups and subgroups, most of which have opposing interests.  From our very first moments, we will see evidence of this.

Again, incentives are not behaviors.  Some neighbors won’t steal land no matter how easy this is.  Some neighbors won’t be suspicious of their neighbors and will not take any precautions to protect their land.  But we all see the walls all around us.  In some cases, they are high and strong walls with broken bottles set in the top to cut up anyone who tries to cross. 

Recall the way people from territorial sovereignty societies descried the societies they saw.  They were used to societies that walled everyone from everyone else and where everyone was suspicious—with good reason—that anything they didn’t protect would be stolen.  Peter Myrtar described the system in Haiti this way:

 

 ‘They seem to live in the golden world, in open gardens not entrenched with dikes, divided with hedges, or defended with walls.  They deal truly with one another, without laws, without books, and without judges.’

Other Divisions:  Classes

Our people are from all walks of life. We have butchers, bakers, bankers, brewers, mechanics, and equipment operators.  Most of us specialized in one skill.  We learned how to do something specific either in school or at work.  We learned what could go wrong if we made mistakes.  (Usually, we had to fix them, on our own time; some people had to pay for the damage they caused.)  Then, over the years, we did whatever it is that we learned how to do over and over. We have very specific skills. 

Only a few of us know everything there is to know about rice farming and are in a position to do all of these things themselves, without help.  In fact, even people who have been involved in this field are going to have a lot of problems.  Kathy is skilled at hiring people to do each of the jobs and making sure they do the jobs properly. She can’t actually do this work herself, because she is handicapped.  (She was badly injured in the wreck and can’t even stand up without help.)   There is a perfect time to take in the rice.  Harvest too early and it will be green and rot or start to ferment.  Wait too long and the grain falls off of the stalks onto the ground and you won’t be able to collect it.  Kathy knows the right time.  But she can’t actually do the work.  Most of the grain on her farm will be lost. 

Others will have no idea what to do. They may get some rice harvested, but nearly as much as a crew that had the right tools and a skilled operator making sure they did the work right.  Some people are likely to be overwhelmed by the prospect of being responsible for operating a farm.  They will see a lot of things that need to be done but won’t know which to do first. Others may simply be lazy.  They won’t get out of bed until noon and will stall so long that, by the time they are ready to work, there won’t be enough daylight to get the work done. 

Some farmers, of course, will realize the work has to be done and figure out how to do it.  They bring in the same amount of rice, per acre, as would have been harvested if a professional had been in charge of organizing the harvest and she had hired people she who could do each of the jobs. In other words, they could collect the same 3,000 pounds of rice per acre used in the previous example.  If you are good enough to make this happen, you will bring in 4,500 pounds of rice on a 1.5 acre farm.

It is easier to understand flows of value if we have a tool to measure the value, so let’s say that we start using dollars with the same value as before. 

 

Money in the society based on the principle of territorial sovereignty:

We could easily use paper money in the natural law society because no one owned the rice so we could put it all into central storage and then use paper certificates to divide it.  Since we all trust that the paper money will be redeemable for one pound of rice per dollar, we can accept paper dollars in exchange for things we sell with confidence.

In societies built on territorial sovereignty, people often don’t trust paper money because there is no general global agreement (among the entire human race) about the value of each piece of paper. When people don’t trust paper money, they often use other things, with the most common ‘things used for money’ being rare metals like gold and silver.  People refine the metals and cast them into coins with a standard size, shape, and weight. Each coin is given a name (for example, a ‘silver dollar’ or a ‘one troy ounce gold Koala’) and stamped with an image to help people identify it.  Often, when people aren’t willing to accept paper money printed by governments, the governments switch to gold or silver coins. 

When the United States was formed in 1776, the founders immediately began printing paper money, called the Continental Dollar and used it to buy things needed for the war against England.  People didn’t trust the issuer (which called itself ‘the government of the United States of America’ but had no real power at first) and wouldn’t accept the money.  It became worthless.  (There is a saying ‘not worth a continental’ that some people use today to refer to something that people claim has value but really has none.)  The government decided to adopt the Spanish silver 8 reales note (called ‘pieces of eight’ or ‘Spanish dollars’) for money and, when people wouldn’t accept the continentals, they paid in silver dollars.  The Spanish dollar had a fixed content of 0.7734 troy ounces of silver, alloyed with other metals to make a coin weighing exactly 0.8593 troy ounces.  Initially, the United States government used dollars minted by the Spanish mint.  In 1784 it began minting its own silver dollars with the same specifications.  United States silver dollars had these exact specifications until 1964.  

For this example, let’s say that the casino safe didn’t have paper United States dollars, it had silver United States silver dollars, minted before 1964.  Say the company was operating this cruse as a part of its silver jubilee (celebrating 25 years in business) and its casino was using only silver dollars for this cruise. People could by silver dollars with the currency of their country when they boarded and then would use silver dollars to buy things on the ship (at rates that state ‘in silver’ that were much lower than the prices in paper United States money) and in the casino. They were told that when the cruise ended, they could either sell their silver dollars back to the cruise company for the market price in their own country’s currency, or keep them as souvenirs and/or sell them later.  They were real United States silver dollars and have a market value all over the world, even in the 21st century when they are no longer officially United States currency.

A lot of people bought silver dollars (or won them in the casino) and had them at the time of the wreck.  There casino safe also had a lot of silver dollars. When we divided the land, we also divided certain things that might be useful that were in the ship.  The silver dollars in the casino safe were divided equally:  everyone got the same amount.  After it was over, everyone had some silver dollars. 

After we divided the land, some farmers fell on hard times right away.  They started trading anything they had for food, including the silver dollars. These dollars made their way the farmers that were better off.  (They were the ones with food to trade for them.)  Eventually, many people had no silver dollars left.  They traded other things for food.  Eventually, they had nothing to trade except their land and began ‘selling’ their land, or trading it for food. 

Only farmers who were relatively good at running their farms had extra food left over to trade for silver and other things. These people wound up with the silver dollars.  They began to trade for the things they needed.  They needed something to use to measure the value of the things they were trading and decided to use silver as a common denominator.  At first, there was no fixed relationship between the value of a pound of rice and a silver dollar.  But, over time, a ‘market price’ developed. 

If we want to compare societies, it helps to have a common way to measure flows of value.  For the sake of this example, let’s say that the market price of rice is either exactly $1 per pound or so close to $1 that any differences aren’t important for practical purposes. 

Different Capabilities to Operate Farms

Our group had a very diverse population.  Some people are young, some are old.  Some are healthy, others have various ailments.  Some know how to tell if rice is ripe and ready to come off of the stalks; others wouldn’t be able to boil rice if they had a video to follow. At the end of the year, different people will end up with different amounts of rice. 

Some will not have enough to keep them alive for the rest of the year, until the next harvest.  They will have to trade whatever they have to offer with the few who have some excess or they won’t eat.

At first, they will trade their personal possessions.  They can get by without their jewelry; most of us brought more than one pair of shoes; we have a few personal items we can trade for food. (Laptops and phones aren’t going to be worth much because we don’t have any electricity; we don’t have any common income we can use to pay people to provide any services at all.) 

Eventually, some people who need food will have nothing to trade for food other than their land.  They will begin to sell parts of their farm.  They will start to trade their land for food. 

We would expect them to sell mostly to their neighbors.

They could sell one square foot at a time or they could agree to move the boundaries between their farms and their neighbors in ways that increase the neighbor’s land and decrease theirs, in exchange for certain amounts of rice or money.

Of course, if you can’t get enough to keep you alive on 1.5 acres of land, you certainly aren’t going to be able to get enough on less than 1.5 acres. Once you start selling, you will have to keep selling and selling.  If you have ever been hungry—I mean really hungry—you will know how painful the decision to sell land can be.  If you have ever heard your children crying with hunger, you will know how hard it is to leave anything unsold if you can sell it to get food to ease their pain.

Other people will be good farmers.  Even the best farmers aren’t going to have enormous amounts of rice however, because they only have 1.5 acres per person in their household.  They will have small surpluses and will able to buy small amounts of land.  But each time they increase the size of their farms, their surpluses grow.  They have more to trade for land and can buy more land.

As time passes, the land ownership will become concentrated.  This happens in all societies built on this kind of ownability of land.  We may try very, very hard to start out in with an equal distribution of land.  But it won’t matter how good of a job we do to start; the distribution won’t stay equal for long.

In time, some people will have no land at all.  They will now have nothing to trade for food but their time.  They will go from farm to farm begging for any work they can do to get enough to keep them and their families alive a little longer. 

Others will have large farms.  Some will own so much land they will have enough to support themselves and workers. They will hire people to do the work on their farms.

Aggravating Factors

Remember, this land is bountiful.  This was very easy to see when we had the natural law society: we could hire the best farm manager in the human race, in this case Kathy, to take in the rice. Kathy could then hire the best people available for each job.  They would all do their work quickly, efficiently and, most importantly for us, cheaply. 

No person is responsible for rice production.  Nature produced rice.  We only collected it and replanted it, so nature could do the same thing next year as it did this year.  Since we did everything with great efficiency, only a small amount of labor and other inputs were needed to collect the rice.  After we fully paid for these inputs, we had enormous amounts of rice left over.

People won’t be as efficient in sovereignty-based societies for several reasons.

The first involves skills.

Recall that the best farmer in our group, Kathy, was seriously injured and will probably not be able to do the hard labor needed to actually collect the rice, even on her own plot.  In the natural law society, she only managed and didn’t have to do any hard work.  In the hundred percent ownability society (sovereignty-based society), she will have to do everything herself.  Even the very best farmer on Earth is probably not going to produce enough to keep herself from starving to death (Kathy is very likely to soon lose her land and, since she can’t do hard work, she will have no income and probably starve to death).

A lot of other people had specific skills that Kathy found useful in collecting the rice, but these people didn’t have the general skills needed to be good farmers. Almost certainly, the land won’t provide as much grain for the benefit of the members of the human race (the human population of the Earth, which means all of us, taken together) as it produced in the natural law society. 

Free Cash Flows

A few people will be very good.  They will be able to produce enough to hire workers to do all the work on the farm, and even hire managers and organizers to make sure everything runs smoothly, and will still have money left over. 

Their properties will produce flows of free cash. 

If they don’t want to do anything, they don’t have to do anything. They just sit back and collect the free money. 

At first, when farms are small, people will only have small free cash flows.  But some will have so much in free cash flows that they will have money left over after they pay all of their living expenses.

They will look for something to do with the left over money. 

They will have opportunities to ‘invest’ it. 

They can find people who are in dire straits and can’t make enough from their land to feed their families and offer to give them a lump sum of money or a pile of food in exchange for some of their land.  In many cases, these people will have no choice but to accept the offer. Land will be ‘sold.’ 

The people with small farms, the poor, will get poorer.

The people with large farms, the rich, will get richer. 

3: Pastland

Written by Annie Nymous on . Posted in 1: Possible Societies, 2: Part Two: Natural Law Societies, Books

Imagine that you are looking on the internet and find a cruise that has some luxury cabins available at almost unbelievably low rates.  Impulsively, you book passage.  I see the same ad and book a room myself.  The ship leaves from Tampa, Florida and heads southwest toward Cozumel, Mexico.

We are in the open water when a giant bright white cloud appears.  It surrounds us like a tornado and lifts us up.  It carries us along, faster and faster, eventually moving us so fast that light itself starts to bend.  The process then starts to reverse, and light straightens out.  We go slower and slower.  Then we hit against something hard—a piece of land.  The water starts to recede.  We are carried along on the receding water for several horrifying hours with no idea what is happening to us.

Finally, we come to a stop.

None of us on the ship realize this yet, but the realities of human existence have changed.  A government somewhere was testing a new type of nuclear bomb.  The military of that nation was trying to build a device that would send out a special kind of electromagnetic pulse (EMP) to destroy electronic devices.  Many of these bombs were tested in history, starting in the 1950s. But this one had some components that had never been tested before.  Sometimes, materials act differently than scientists predict in the intense heat, pressure, and gamma radiation at the center of a nuclear explosion. 

The scientists had hoped that the new materials would lead to a tunable EMP, one that would destroy the enemy’s electronics but not its own.  But they made a tiny, tiny, mistake in their calculations.  The materials didn’t act as they expected; instead, they created a momentary vibration in the space-time field. 

This was unfortunate for the majority of the people on the planet Earth: the vibration led to an ‘unsyncing’ of the motion of the electrons the in atoms that make up our world.  They were only out of sync for a tiny fraction of a microsecond.  But when the distortion ended, the electrons couldn’t find their way back into orbit around their nuclei.  All of the atoms of the great majority of the planet Earth disintegrated into bosons, quarks, and mesons that will never again be atoms—let alone a planet people can live on—for the rest of time.

The people on the cruise ship were lucky, however.

The space-time distortion field was shaped like a tornado.  It had powerful forces at the edges but included a calm eye at the center where almost nothing happened.  We were in the exact right place to catch the calm eye in the center of the distortion. The space-time distortion sent our people, our ship, and several thousand cubic miles of ocean water back a little more than 4 million years in time.  We are now in the remote past.

We have gone back to before the first humans arrived on this world.

This makes us the world’s first humans.

The First Human Societies

Since no humans have existed, no human societies have existed either.

This means that the people in our group don’t have to follow anyone’s rules about how societies are supposed to work.

We haven’t inherited a legacy of ‘national debts’ that we must repay.  We don’t have to accept that we have traditional religious or racial enemies anymore, and tax our people so we can build militaries to attack them and defend ourselves against their attacks.  We don’t have to make sure that the nations, corporations, and individuals who ‘own’ parts of the world are able to keep people who don’t ‘own’ from benefiting from the existence of the part of the world that belongs to them, because there are no owners.  We don’t have to make sure that the imaginary lines called ‘borders’ that determine the limits of ‘nations’ are respected, because there are no borders and no nations.  We don’t have to pay taxes to cover the cost of police to enforce the existing order, because there is no existing order to enforce.

We have complete freedom as to what kind of society to form.  We can determine what ‘modes of existence’ we want.  We can make our own rules.

Practical Matters

The space-time wave moved us hundreds of miles from our previous location and washed us up, along with several thousand cubic miles of ocean water, deep into the interior of a continent. When the water receded, it dragged the ship several miles and tore the bottom of the ship to pieces, leaving the upper part lodged in a muddy swamp.  The trauma killed more than a thousand of the people on the ship.

As soon as the ship comes to a stop, the people who were physically able to do so began working to rescue the trapped and save any who could be saved.  A few of our people had medical experience.  These people set up a triage center and makeshift emergency hospital on an upper deck. 

People who find injured people bring them there. 

A minister locates a parcel of land to use as a cemetery so we can bury the dead, to prevent an outbreak of disease. For several days, all able-bodied people help with the rescue attempts and a burial party makes sure the dead are buried.

Finally, we get to a stopping point and have a meeting so we can take stock of our situation.

The social director of the cruise ship opens the meeting.  She does this in part because she knows many of us—having organized the welcome party and some drinking games right after we left—and in part because no one who is in any position of authority is left alive.  The ship’s captain and everyone who might claim to have authority perished in the wreck.  She wants to make sure we realize she isn’t claiming to be in charge of anything: she has just come forward because no one else came forward first.

Like the rest of us, she has been digging through the rubble to try to find and help survivors.  She hasn’t slept for days, she is filthy, and her clothing is torn and covered with dirt and dried blood.  She thanks everyone who pitched in to help and says that this has saved many lives.  She tells us she has counted and there are 1,000 survivors, including people who are injured but are going to recover.

She says she has no idea where we are or how long it will take to get us rescued.  (She has no idea we are in the past.  She has been working so hard to save lives she hasn’t had time to worry about such relatively unimportant things.) She asks if anyone can shed some light on this and another woman comes to the front.

The other woman is an  engineer of electronics who has been trying to get the ship’s electronic systems working.  She has gotten everything going but hasn’t been able to reach anyone on the standard rescue channels.  The GPS, satellite TV and satellite phone appear to be working but she can’t pick up any satellite signals.  She had a simple battery-powered satellite finder in her luggage.  She has been scanning the sky to try to find satellites, but her device hasn’t picked up any of them. She finds this very strange: there are supposed to be thousands of satellites in the sky.  They seem to have all disappeared.

She is about ready to step down when she pauses to tell us something else: all of the clocks on the instruments have a reading that she can’t figure out: they read the year as ‘-4,000,000.’ She says that this might mean ‘4,000,000 BC.’ This seemed so strange that she didn’t want to mention it, but she says it is possible we are all in the remote past.  She will keep trying to reach someone and get us rescued, but in the meantime, she suggests we try to make the best of what we have.

We may be here for a long time.

Another woman comes up, this time an astronomer.  She tells us that the stars all appear to be out of position from where they should be. We are in an outer spiral arm of a galaxy and are orbiting the center of the galaxy at a speed of about one million miles per day.  This causes the view we get of certain stars and galaxies to shift.  She has calculated that the stars are where they would have been 4,002,020 years before we started on this trip.  This seems to confirm the information on the clocks. It is possible we are in the remote past.

Someone jokingly says, ‘Welcome to Pastland.’ The name sticks.  People start to call our new home ‘Pastland.’

How and Where We Will Live

First, I want to go over some practical realities of our existence like where and how we will live and where we will get food and other necessities of life, so you can see what we have to work with in forming societies:

We will live in our cabins on the ship for the time being.  Although the extreme bottom decks of the ship were destroyed, we can still use most of the rest.  The ship is sitting on land that is more or less level.  People need to sleep somewhere, and people have moved back into their cabins to have places to sleep.

We ended up next to a large river with plenty of flow to turn turbines.  Some of the passengers are handy with tools.  They salvage the ship’s propellers and some other parts and use them to make a power plant to turn the ship’s electricity generators. Many people volunteer to help build the power plant because we really want electricity: it is hot and muggy where we are, and we want our air conditioners back on.

The ship has freshwater piping to all cabins.  Some people rig up a piping system to move water from a clear spring and pump it into the freshwater distribution system.  The ship’s waste treatment plant still works so, once we have water, we can use our toilets.  Since we have both electricity and fresh water, we can take showers, do laundry, and even fill the ship’s swimming pools so we can swim.

The ship that went back in time with us gives us a place to live.  We have water and sanitary facilities.  We only need one thing that we don’t have now to sustain us: food.

The Bounty of the Planet Earth

We are very lucky to have ended up where we are.  Although some people call our landing place a ‘swamp,’ some use an alternate term and call it a ‘freshwater marsh.’ Wild rice grows in this marsh in great abundance. For thousands of years before we got here, this land has had a stable and productive ecosystem, producing large amounts of rice for the benefit of its (non-human) residents.

In the spring, runoff from snowmelt on lands upriver causes the rivers to swell.  When this happens, the water level rises above the level of the land to a depth of about a foot.  This creates the perfect conditions for rice to grow.  Wild rice has grown here every year for thousands of years.

Qqq wild rice here.

Late in the summer, the river flows ease and the water table falls.  By early fall the water table has fallen below the level of the land and the land becomes dry.  The rice ripens to a golden brown and the kernels fall off of the stalks onto the ground.

This has been happening for many thousands of years before we got here.

The wild rice never went to waste. Each year, giant flocks of ducks, geese, cranes, passenger pigeons, and other migratory birds arrived to feast on nature’s bounty.  When winter came and the birds had moved on, possums, raccoons, beaver, otters, minks, muskrats, weasels, deer, elk, and other animals came to share the rice that the birds missed.  In the spring when the water rose, schools of fish—sturgeon, cavefish, shiners, darters, paddlefish, sunfishes, bream, catfish, crappies, and black basses, to name a few—moved in to feast on whatever was left.

The animals didn’t always thoroughly chew the rice kernels, however, and many kernels passed through their digestive systems intact.  This provided seeds for next year’s crop.

The next year, everything happened again.

This land is bountiful and produces large amounts of rice without any need for human effort.  For all of history so far, this bounty has gone to other animals.

But this is going to change.

Humans have abilities that other animals don’t: we can collect the rice at the exact right time of the year and put it into granaries so other animals can’t get it.  We can take the bounty the land produces for ourselves if we want. Other animals will only get any of this rice if we let them have it, either by giving it to them or by deciding not to take it ourselves.

Some Numbers

Some people are curious about whether the land will produce enough to support us and have made some calculations.

Two of them measured the rice-growing area and determined its size: it is 1,500 acres.  They have decided to call this area Pastland Farm.  One person carefully measured out one square foot of land, cut the stalks on that land, removed the kernels and weighed them to get just under 1/20th of one pound per square foot, which works out to 2,100 pounds per acre, or 3.15 million pounds for the entire marsh/farm.  We have 1,000 people so if we divide this rice evenly, we will have 3,150 pounds for each of us per year, or just over 8 pounds for each of us per day.

 

The figures for rice yields come from two sources. One is ‘Travels And Adventures in The Indian Territories Between The Years 1760 And 1776,’ by Alexander Henry. Henry was put into circumstances (described in the book) where he found himself the very first European living among natives in parts of North America where wild rice was a staple food.  He discusses the methods of collecting rice, the amounts of rice obtained from the land, and the trade value of rice in American communities before there was any significant influence from European invaders.

The other is a scholarly work about the same issue: Alfred Jenks: ‘The Wild Rice Gatherers Of The Upper Lakes, A Study in American Primitive Economics.’ This book goes over the realities of existence for these people and provides detailed figures for the rice yields they actually obtained. 

You can find the full text of both books on the PossibleSocieties.com website.

 

Each person needs about 2 pounds of rice per day, as a minimum, to stay alive, so we will clearly have much more than we need.

Kathy and The Pastland Farm

I want to introduce someone who will be involved in some key decisions in this book: 

Kathy, a passenger on this ship, is an experienced rice farmer.  Kathy was seriously injured in the wreck and has been in a coma since it happened.

When she wakes up, lying in a cot set up in our makeshift infirmary on the top deck of our ship, she thinks she is dreaming because she is imagining she is back in her childhood home. Before she even opens her eyes in this dream she is having, she knows where she is from the smell and feel of the air.

The wild rice-producing marshes of Texas have native bacteria that ‘fixes’ nitrogen, taking it from the air (which is 69% nitrogen) and turning it into a form growing plants can use.  The bacteria evolved with the rice, millions of years ago, and the two living organisms depend on each other for survival. The bacteria provide nitrogen that the plant needs, and the plant’s waste products sustain the bacteria.

The bacteria impart an unmistakable smell into the air.  Kathy was raised in Texas rice country and grew up with this smell.  To her, this is the smell of home.  Before she even opens her eyes, she knows where she is.

Not only does she know where she is, she knows what time of year it is and roughly what time of day.  She can feel that the air is heavy with moisture with a powerful sun trying to bore through the mist, just as she remembers from her childhood home before a summer thundershower.  She is afraid to open her eyes for fear that she will find it is just a dream. 

When she summons the courage, she looks out to see the silhouette of the distant hills against the horizon she remembers from her childhood.  This is the same view she got from her bedroom window on the farmhouse that used to stand on this very spot when she was growing up.

She knows this land.  She can tell you what the dirt looks like and what it feels like if you take off your shoes and walk barefoot through the shallow marshes, as she did in her childhood.  (She will warn you that you can’t wear shoes, because they will stick in the muck and you will lose them.)  She can tell you how to locate good spots to fish in the big river and how to find the best spots for wild berries, grapes, fruits, mushrooms, sunflower seeds and other nuts in the surrounding forests.  She can tell you how to find straight softwood trees for poles and very strong hickory for working into tools and other products.

She was practically raised here. Her aunt and uncle had owned the farm that had stood on this very land and her family had spent a great deal of time here.  When she was very young, before her aunt and uncle had switched to hybrid rice that requires chemicals to grow, the farm raised the exact same kind of rice that grows wild here now. She helped with many tasks and knows how to raise it.

When Kathy recovers enough to attend group meetings, the rice is ready to harvest.  She tells us that we have to harvest it quickly because if it gets too dry it will fall onto the ground and be impossible to collect.  Some people are pretty handy with tools and have drawn up plans to build a harvesting machine with a gasoline motor and some other parts found on the ship.  We don’t have any gasoline, but we did find some tanks with ethanol and we can use this for fuel (for next year, people will make more ethanol out of rice, as you will see).

She says she can put the entire operation together for us because she has harvested rice before.  However, she will need to ask some people with specialized skills to help her and she doesn’t feel right asking them to work for nothing.  She wants the ability to pay them somehow.  She knows how to make this work if we have some kind of money.  She knows that the rice this land produced was ‘worth’ about $1 (one British Pound) per pound in the future we came from.  She says it would be nice if we had some kind of money so that she could ‘sell’ the rice (trade it for money) and then use the money to pay her workers.

Money

This book examines a great many different types of societies that are possible for thinking beings with physical needs.  All beings with physical needs must have some thing physical coming in from the world around them to survive.  Humans, for example, need food on a regular basis, to replace the sugars used by our live processes.  If we don’t have this ‘income’ (food) we die. This book uses the term ‘value’ to refer to items that humans need to keep us alive, together with the things we want to make our lives more comfortable.  We need some income in ‘value’ to survive.  If we have more income, we can have better lives. 

It doesn’t matter what type of society we have:  we need an income of value.  Always.

To compare all of the different societies, we will need some way to put the amounts of value in context.  How much value do you need to stay alive?  How much extra value might you get to make your life more comfortable if things worked differently?  People have created tools that can help us understand flows of value.

Later, when we look at territorial sovereignty societies, we will see that they have special needs that make some kind of money essential:  they can’t work very well, or for very long, on barter economies or economies that don’t have a standard way to measure and transfer value. 

 

Why?

War is an inevitable part of these societies. War is an incredibly complex process and a country which can organize itself for efficiency will have great advantages over a country that is inefficient.  Having a tool people can use to measure everything of value, from the value of a stick of chewing gum to a nuclear aircraft carrier, allows trading on a vast scale and creates great efficiency. 

The leaders of some countries in the past tried to keep their countries going without money, creating barter, labor credit, or other assorted accounting systems, but these systems were not as efficient as systems that had a tool that was a universal store of value that could be applied to all things that are for sale.  They couldn’t extract as much wealth from their citizens (as taxes) as countries that used money so they couldn’t build as many weapons or support as large of armies as countries that used money.  They had disadvantages in war and were defeated by countries that did use money, which moved their systems into these locations as soon as they took over.  As a result, systems that tried to operate without money disappeared and money-based economies have dominated territorial sovereignty societies for at least the last two thousand years (as far back as records go).  

 

When we get into the discussions of Part Three, we will see that the concept of money is actually quite complex, at least in societies where people can buy parts of the earth with the same tool that people use to buy bowls of rice.  (What is the right amount of ‘bowls of rice equivalent in money’ to pay for ‘the ‘the drainage basin of the Missouri river and its tributaries’ [the legal description for the Louisiana purchase]?  It is hard to compare bowls of rice to drainage basins of massive rivers. The tool of money doesn’t really appear to be versatile enough to use for both of these things, yet it is used for both.  How does this work?  It can be understood, but it is extremely complicated.) 

However, to compare societies in general, we don’t need to know all of the scientific details of money.  (In the same way that you don’t need to understand the scientific details of jet aircraft to understand how to book and get on a flight from Chicago to Paris.)  We all have practical experience with money and know how to use this tool in practical situations.  When dealing with the simple things that money can do, like helping to distribute the food a part of the world produces for the people, money isn’t hard to understand and will work basically the same way in all of the societies we examine. 

This means that, for most people, money is just a tool, in the same way that a hammer is a tool.  They may not know the science behind it and they don’t have to.  It is useful so people use it.

The people of any kind of society can use this tool, just as the people of any society can use a hammer.  We know from historical records that nearly all natural law societies used money of some kind.  American native people used a kind of money that was based on the premise of ‘proof of work’ (the same theoretical construct that backs up Bitcoin). Again, most of them probably had no idea how and why the things they used for money had the value they had, but they knew they did, so they were willing to accept them in trade for things they had for sale. 

Many books that are available on the PossibleSocieties.com website deal with prices in various areas. 

 

Lewis and Clark took a trip from Minnesota to Oregon and back in the early 1800s.  They brought ‘Indian money’ with them to pay for food, lodging, goods, and services along the way.   They discuss their budgeting before they left on the trip, based on their estimates of prices of the things they needed, the purchase of ‘Indian money’ in markets, and the costs of various things they bought along the way.  (The prices were significantly higher than they had anticipated so they ran out of money in Oregon and had to resort to theft, in some cases, to get the things they needed.) 

The book The Wild Rice Gatherers Of The Upper Lakes, A Study in American Primitive Economics explains the economies of the people who lived in the Great Lakes of North America before the conquest of these areas and discusses prices of various items in that system. 

 

I want to use the same standards to measure value in all of the systems examined, to make it easier to compare them. You and I and everyone who might be reading this book will be used to using money for these things because all economies in the 21st century use money for transactions. 

We will be collecting 3,150,000 pounds—more than 15 tons—of rice.  After the harvest, we will have meetings and make decisions about how to divide this rice. It will be very hard for us to do this by distributing physical rice.  Someone suggest that we create some sort of paper certificates that each represent a certain amount of rice.  For example, we could have ‘one pound notes’ that are worth one pound of rice. We could have ‘ten pound notes’ that are worth ten pounds, and for large transactions, we could have 100 pound notes that are worth 100 pounds. 

We want certificates that people won’t be able to counterfeit very easily.  (Otherwise, people will simply print their own money whenever they want it.) After some discussion, someone points out that we already have counterfeit-resistant paper certificates: the ship’s casino has a safe that contains a large amount of British currency.  This safe hasn’t been opened since the wreck because no one has had any need for British currency.  (The country of England doesn’t exist yet, so its currency is basically just pieces of paper to us here.) We can use the British pound certificates in the safe as rice certificates, with each $1 representing one pound of rice.

Here is how it will work: after Kathy has harvested the 3.15 million pounds of rice she will put it into the cargo hold of the ship.  We will call the cargo hold our ‘treasury.’  It will hold the real value we own, the ‘treasure.’  We will then issue a one pound note for each pound of rice in the treasury.  We will put this on a table in our meeting room.  We will then have a meeting to decide how to divide this money.  If you get a $1 note, you get a certificate that you can trade for a pound of rice any time you want (or at least any time the treasurer’s office is open). 

We will elect a treasurer to deal with the actual transactions. She starts by asking if anyone here has British currency.  For this example, let’s say no one has any.  (If they had it, they could turn it in; to make sure no one has any currency hidden away, she can scan all of the money that is valid to record the serial numbers and any currency with a number not in the database would be assumed to be counterfeit and worthless.  This could be done but it is easier to just assume no one has any.)  

Now, all British currency that exists in our world is in a safe.  She opens the safe, on camera and with a witness, and takes out exactly $3.15 million.

She puts this money on a set of tables in the center of the room.  We will now have a meeting and decide who we want to get the rice in the treasury. If we want a certain person to get a pound of rice, we will give her a one pound note.  The treasurer has posted hours where she will trade a pound of rice for a one pound note on request from anyone who has money.

 

Note about pronouns:

In this book, female personal pronouns will be used to refer to unspecified individuals of either sex.  The treasurer, and all other decision makers referred to with female pronouns, may be male or female.

How We Will Distribute the Money

Before the harvest, Kathy asked various people with special skills to help her with certain tasks, and asked for laborers to come forward to help with tasks that didn’t require skills. She told them that she thinks that people who help with work need to be compensated for their work at a fair rate. She told them that, after the harvest, she is going to work hard through whatever system evolves to make sure that they get fully compensated for the things they do, at the same rates they would have gotten back in the 21st century. 

Kathy expects the group to agree to her requests.  We all know that it takes work to harvest grain.  We want people to be willing to do this work in the future.  If we pay them, at rates they think are fair, we can be confident they will do the work, year after year, and the rice will be brought in and put into the cargo hold, where people who need to eat can get it.

At the meeting, Kathy is going to be very convincing and get her way: the people who work on the farm are going to get paid the same amount of money they would have made in the 21st century United States for doing the same work.

The value of a dollar will be about the same as it was back in the 21st century United States:  it was enough to buy a pound of fully organic, 100% chemical-free wild rice there and it will buy the same amount here. 

We will see that people can make a great many things out of rice or parts of the rice plant; people will start to make these things and offer them for sale at prices that reflect the input materials, their labor, and a reasonable profit.  Because labor and material costs will be about the same as in our 2020 world, the costs of the many other products they will make out of rice will be about the same as in the 2020 world, as measured in United States dollars. 

Costs of Harvesting

Humans don’t make rice. 

Nature makes rice. 

When we got here, the rice was already here.  All we had to do was collect it.

Since we came back with an understanding of technology and a lot of parts to use to make machines, we were able to make machines that allowed us to harvest the entire crop in only a few days. Kathy knew how much money people needed for doing these things back in the 21st century and wants her people to make the same amount in Pastland.  She has put together rates that lead to about the same total costs of harvesting and replanting she would have paid back in the 21st century. These costs total $500,000. There are huge stacks of money on the table.  She is going to ask for $500,000 of this money to pay her workers and suppliers.

Since we collect all the rice, there will be no natural reseeding.  We therefore have to put some of this rice back into the ground as seeds for a crop next year.  She intends to buy the rice seed (trade money for it) and she needs 190,000 pounds of seed.  If we want her to make sure the same crop comes in next year, we will have to give her another $190,000 to buy the seed, and another $10,000 for the cost of planting, a total of $200,000. 

She is therefore going to ask for $700,000 of the $3.15 million that is on the table.  If she gets this, she can make sure everyone who does any work on the farm or provides any supplies gets fully paid at rates that are about the same as they were in the 2020 United States, and we have enough to reseed next year so we will get the same crop next year. 

Organization and Management of Food Collection

Kathy makes this request.  We vote and approve it.  Kathy has asked one of her friends to help with the money transactions.  Her friend is a professional accountant named ‘Sara.’  Sara will keep the books and make sure everyone is paid.  Sara comes up to the front with a luggage cart and takes stacks of money, until she has taken $700,000 off the table and put it onto the luggage cart. 

The treasurer has her sign for the money. 

Sara will make sure everyone is paid.

Sara asks to speak.  She tells the group that we have fully compensated everyone who provided labor, supplies, equipment, fuel, and other things needed for the operation of the harvest.  But we haven’t paid everyone who did anything important.  In fact, we haven’t paid the most important person. 

Kathy has not done any physical work. She was badly injured in the wreck and hasn’t been able to leave her bed.  She organized everything on paper, made calls to round up the workers, got them to give daily reports on their activity, and had people she trusted check on them to make sure they were honest in their reports. 

Kathy is a very nice and friendly person and a lot of people like her.  She couldn’t do everything herself because of her health, so she asked her friends to help out with some of the tasks needed to organize the operation, manage the workers, and take care of the accounting and other details. 

Sara falls into this category. She helped out with the accounting because Kathy asked her to help.  She did it as a favor.  After she started, she realized that Kathy really shouldn’t be doing this kind of work anyway:  Kathy was on meds and might make mistakes in her data entry or calculations.  Sara has done this kind of work for 20 years and could do these things in her sleep. 

If she had been doing this kind of work in the future, before she took this trip, she would have charged $5,000 for her services.  It didn’t take a lot of time so she wouldn’t charge for ‘hours of work.’  Her clients weren’t paying for ‘hours of work,’ they were paying to make sure a very complicated task was done properly.  In this case she did it all for free—this time, at least.  But who knows what will happen in the future?  If Kathy gets fully paid for all of the things she did, she can take care of Sara too, giving her enough to justify doing the same work next year.

A few other people also provided a great deal of assistance.  One person used to be in the field of ‘human resources’ back in the future.  Her job was finding out who could do what and finding out how to best utilize the skills and talents of the various people involved in the project.  The human resources expert created a database that showed what skills were available.  She found out who could do what and talked to the people who could do various things to see if they were wiling to help out.   After she found people who could help, she told them what Kathy had in mind:  she intended to ask for money to pay them at the same rates they had been paid in the future for the same work.  She found people who were willing to do the work, under the condition that Kathy kept her word and did everything she could to get them paid.  The HR expert helped a lot: if she hadn’t been there, Kathy may not have been able to find the people needed to make things work smoothly. The HR expert didn’t ask for pay, but Sara says we should make sure Kathy has enough to pay her anyway. Everyone who did anything to make sure the grain got into storage should get something, even if it is just a token to show that we aren’t taking them for granted and are going to take care of people who do these things in the future. 

How many people were involved? How much money should they get for the things they did?

Sara says she doesn’t know.

Kathy made these arrangements. Only Kathy knows. 

However, we can make a pretty good guess:

Back in the 21st century United States, certain companies kept teams of people to do the work of organizing and managing properties that generated revenue.  Sara says that she used to work for a company in this field and knows that they would have charged $50,000 a year to do the things that Sara did, if these things had taken place in the 21st century.  Sara suggests we give Kathy this amount of money as her compensation for organizing everything and managing it, with the understanding that she will take care of everyone who stepped forward to help her so that they won’t feel anyone is taking advantage of them and that we all appreciate their efforts. 

We discuss this issue.

Later in this book, I will discuss some complicated arguments that we might expect at this point.  There are a lot of people who feel that it is immoral to pay people who simply organize and don’t do any actual physical work anything at all.  If we do pay them, they think that it isn’t moral for them to get more, per hour of work they do, than laborers get.  The people get angry when they find out that the people who don’t do any real work and merely organize—often not really doing anything significant at all—get paid at rates that work out to be hundreds of times more, per hour of work, than people who do hard physical work. 

They think this is immoral and won’t accept it.

We will also see that people in some real-world natural law societies refused to pay for organizational services at rates that encouraged people to gain the required skills.  In these systems, no one really knew how to organize tasks that were needed for complex operations like the operation of a rice farm.  We will see that it was quite frequent for people in these situations to not get enough to eat and end up with extreme hardship and mass starvation. No one knew what had to be done to keep food coming in and no one had any real incentive to go through the effort to figure this out.  There was food out in the fields but, because they couldn’t bring it in properly, store it, or make sure everyone was compensated for the things they did, the food went the same places it had gone before humans arrived (to other animals) and the humans starved to death.  Humans are capable of planning and organizing.  We can do these things.  But if we don’t do them (perhaps because of a belief that paying certain people is unfair), we have no advantages to compensate for our incredible disadvantages relative to other animals.  (For example, a great need for energy to keep our uninsulated and unprotected bodies at the proper temperature, the need to be basically unconscious for a third of the day while we sleep, and the need to spend more than a decade to raise each newborn to self-sufficiency; if we don’t have advantages to offset these disadvantages, we are not going to be able to compete with birds, fish, possums, and other animals without these disadvantages.) 

Some natural law societies refused to pay for organizational and management services, but some realized the importance of these skills and set up systems so that they had well organized systems to take in food and other necessities.  Those that did this survived; those that did not perished. 

It is important for the points of this book that the people in our group accept the need to have these things done and agree to take care of the people who do them so they keep doing them.

Sara has proposed we pay Kathy $50,000 a year, with the understanding that she use this money to pay the people who helped her enough to show that we aren’t taking them for granted; she can keep the rest of the money herself.  We approve the expense.

Incomes

This makes a total of $750,000 that has been taken out of the pile of money.  It started with $3.15 million, so now there is $2.4 million there. 

Everyone who has done anything associated with planting, management of the farm during the growing season, or harvest, has been fully compensated for everything they do.  No one in our group can claim to be responsible for the existence of the rice this extra money represents. 

Yet it must go somewhere. 

I want to skip over the discussions were we argue about how to divide this money for now and discuss what would happen if we simply divide it evenly. 

There is $2.4 million on the table. There are 1,000 of us.  Everyone gets $2,400.  The treasurer calls out our names, one by one, and we come to the front and get our cash. 

Everyone on earth gets $2,400 of this $2.4 million. 

This is a kind of ‘basic income’ that everyone gets:  it is the foundation of their total income.  People who work in production get more.  (It doesn’t make sense to exclude them from the divisions of the left over money because they worked; this punishes them for working.)  People who organize or help with management get more. But everyone gets at least $2,400.

A Basic Economy

You are there in Pastland.

You get a pile of cash.

Each $1 bill is a receipt for 1 pound of rice.  You have enough money to buy a total of 2,400 pounds of rice over the course of the next year.  This works out to 7 pounds of dry rice every day.  This is a great deal more rice than you could eat.  It would be enough (dry) rice to make 15 pounds of boiled rice each day.

You could not eat this much.

You would explode.

For a few weeks, however, most people live on boiled rice, because no other foods are available.

One of our people, a woman named Tanya, used to be an organic duck and goose egg farmer back in the future, before we took this trip.  She buys several hundred pounds of rice and puts it out to attract ducks and geese. She puts several small piles of rice out in the open that they will see from the sky, in order to attract them to the ground.  She then makes little trails of rice that go to nests she has built for the birds out of rice straw, in an area she can protect from predators. 

Ducks and geese see the rice piles and come down to investigate.  They follow the trails to the nests.  They like the nests and spend time there.  Birds have horrible night vision and have to bed down for the night; they often have a hard time finding safe places.  The nests are safe (Tanya makes sure of this).  They spend a lot of time there, eating the food Tanya puts out for them. They lay eggs in the nests. 

The birds are basically acting as protein factories.  They take in the rice, which is carbohydrates, turn it into eggs, which are mostly proteins, and then lay the eggs.  Birds’ bodies are very efficient at this conversion process.  (There is an evolutionary reason for this efficiency: eggs are very good food for many animals.  Most of the eggs that birds lay get stolen.  If they weren’t efficient at producing more eggs, they wouldn’t have enough chicks to replace them and would die out, to be replaced by more efficient birds.) 

Tanya knows how to keep her egg production high.  She keeps track of the amount that each bird eats and the number of eggs it lays. Birds that don’t have a very high ‘conversion efficiency’ of carbohydrates into proteins become dinner themselves.  Those that lay very well remain in her flock.  Those that lay extremely well may be allowed to keep their chicks and raise them, to make sure the next generation lays very well. 

The ship’s internet is still working. Tanya sets up a website she calls ‘Tanya’s Organic Eggs’ and offers eggs for sale.

Now people can buy two things with their money: rice or eggs.

One man sees some wild goats and puts out some rice to attract them.  Over a few weeks, he brings them closer and eventually he can pet them. A few weeks later he is feeding them daily.  Some of the doe goats he feeds are pregnant; they have kids.  Doe goats produce a lot more milk than their kids need.  He milks them and opens a dairy where he sells milk, cream, and butter. A lot of people like these things; demand is high, and the supply is low (at least at first) so he makes a lot of money doing this.  Others realize they can make money doing the same thing.  After some time, several people are offering dairy products and the prices come down to the level where everyone who wants dairy products can afford them.

Wild pigs live in this area.  A woman puts out some rice porridge to attract them.  They love it.  (Uncooked grains are very hard for pigs to digest so they generally ignore them.  But the cooked rice is like a feast to them.)  She puts out the porridge every night.  After a week, she digs a trap, covers it with straw, and balances a bowl of porridge on some sticks on top of the trap.  A pregnant sow drops into the trap and soon she has a dozen piglets and a sow.

She puts up an ad on the ship’s internet advertising that she will pick up anyone’s food waste at no cost, to feed her pigs.  People start putting out their food waste for her to pick up.

Pigs are like living garbage disposals.  They eat just about anything and turn it into pork.  She makes a deal with a person who used to be a butcher back in the future: she will provide the live animals, the butcher can turn them into bacon, ham, pork chops, and ribs, and they will sell the meat over the internet and split the income.

A person begins to grind the rice into flour and several people start baking breads, noodles, tortillas, cakes, and cookies with the flour and selling all manner of baked goods.  You can place an order over the internet and they will deliver the baked goods to your cabin door.

One person in our group, a man named ‘Dennis,’ used to own a microbrewery back in Spain.  The main ingredient in beer is rice.  Dennis starts making beer and selling it in one of the ship’s bars.

One of our people used to make ethanol for fuel for vehicles back in Indonesia before she took this trip. She made ethanol out of rice and understands the method: boil the rice for several days to turn it into a mash, let the mash ferment for several weeks until the sugars turn into alcohol, then distill the mash.  After the first distillation, she gets a mixture of rice water and alcohol, called ‘saké.’  This is an alcoholic beverage that a lot of people like to drink.  After the second distillation, she gets pure grain alcohol, called ‘ethanol.’

She makes both saké and grain alcohol. She sells the saké to Dennis to resell in his bar and sells the ethanol to people who need fuel, like the operator of the harvesting machine. 

Wild grapes grow along the river. Several people start making wine. They sell their products to Dennis to resell in his bar.  Crawdads, catfish, and lobster live in the waterways.  People catch them and sell them.  Various people open clubs and restaurants to serve meals and drinks. The clubs hire musicians to attract guests.

One of our people, a woman named ‘Sally,’ used to run a bank in England before she took this trip.  She knows a lot of people don’t like carrying cash. They would rather just have a card and pay for everything with the card.  She opens a bank here in Pastland: she will take in deposits, hold the money for the owners, and allow them to make withdrawals with cards. (On cruise ships, people use their electronic door keys for credit cards to buy things.  Everyone already has a card and there are thousands of electronic card readers all over the ship.)

Initially, Sally charges very high fees.  Several other people open their own banks to compete with her, driving bank fees down.  You can choose to keep your money in a bank; if you decide to do this, you can decide which bank to use.

Now that we have banks, most people don’t even bother with cash: they have their incomes deposited directly into their bank accounts and pay for everything through electronic deductions over the internet or with their debit cards.

How Do We Live?

No one pays for shelter.

We all live in our cabins on the ship.

Volunteers have set up an electricity system, a water system and an internet.  (We will vote to pay them soon:  we want them to know we aren’t taking them for granted so they will keep working.)  We get electricity, water, and internet for free. 

All we need coming in on a continuing basis is food.

Over the course of the year, people will trade their money for rice.  The amount of rice in the cargo hold will go down and the amount of money in circulation will go down at the same rate.  (When a $1 bill is traded for rice, the serial number is taken out of the database of ‘currency in circulation:  this is no longer money.  The bill is put back into the safe to be taken out after the harvest when we again have to trade rice for money.)  By the end of the year, a lot of people are getting pretty short on cash. But then Kathy organizes a harvest again, puts 3.15 million pounds of rice in storage, and we go through the same process. 

Everyone gets $2,400 again. 

Common Services

The electricity plant was put in place by volunteers.  When we first got here, it was hot and everyone wanted air conditioning.  A lot of people pitched in to build the plant and it now exists.  It has a turbine that sits in the flow of the ricer and runs a generator.  It doesn’t take a lot of work to keep it operating, but someone has to check on it.  A volunteer has been doing this.

The water system is also pretty automatic.  Most of the time, no one has to touch it.  But, once in a while, someone has to go to make sure the pumps are working right and keeping the tanks on the ship at the property level.  The internet works pretty seamlessly, but sometimes it fails and someone has to unplug the servers, wait 10 seconds, and plug them in again, to get them to reboot.  We also have a treasurer and granary operator who work for free.

 We want these people to know we appreciate their effort.  We decide to pay them and vote on the services individually.  At the end of the election, we wind up spending $400,000 on public services.  

This doesn’t reduce the amount of value that each of us gets out of the $2.4 million left after paying production costs.  We still each get $2,400 a year; we just get $2,000 of this in cash and $400 of it as ‘free’ electricity, water, treasury services, grain storage, and other services.  We are all getting a minimum of $2,400 a year from the land.